Insuring the Uninsured through Association Health Plans

The American health care system consists largely of employer-based group health insurance. After World War II, employers offered health care plans in order to attract employees. As the numbers of employer-provided health plans grew, the federal government and the states regulated them heavily.

One of the unintended consequences of increasing government regulation was to increase the numbers of people without health insurance. The high cost of complying with different state regulations has raised the cost of employer-sponsored health plans, leading many small businesses to drop coverage altogether. By the end of 2001, the Census Bureau estimated more than 41 million Americans were uninsured – many of them young, healthy people with modest or low incomes.

Part of the solution to insuring the uninsured is the creation of Association Health Plans (AHPs). These are plans created for individuals and groups who belong to associations that are related to jobs, careers, or hobbies and interests. The potential for growth of this type of insurance is quite large – given a favorable regulatory climate.

Proponents of AHPs argue that they have great potential to insure the uninsured. By uniting many small groups with similar interests across the country, AHPs could take full advantage of economies of scale to lower health care costs for their memberships.

  • There are about 15,000 associations throughout the country.
  • Some six million Americans are insured through associations and the number is growing.

AHPs are applicable to a variety of group memberships. For example:

  • The American Association of Retired People offers supplemental medical insurance to all of the Medicare enrollees among its 35 million dues-paying members.
  • The National Association for the Self-Employed (NASE) makes AHP insurance available to its members throughout the country.
  • The National Restaurant Association could offer AHP insurance to restaurant employees in all 50 states, and the National Rifle Association could offer insurance to its members.

Perhaps the most important argument for AHPs is that millions of people who are not covered because of high costs or lack of availability would be able to obtain affordable coverage.

  • A Congressional Budget Office (CBO) analysis of legislation pending in Congress estimates that small businesses can expect to reap savings averaging between 9 percent and 25 percent of the cost of their health insurance premiums.
  • As a result, the CBO estimates that 330,000 – and potentially as many as 2 million – of the currently uninsured would obtain health insurance.
  • CONSAD Research Corporation estimates that expanding AHPs could result in an increase in employer-sponsored insurance coverage of approximately 2.3 million workers and 2.2 million dependents.

Most of the uninsured are connected to the workplace, and most uninsured workers are employees of small businesses that are especially burdened by the lack of competition and by unwise regulations. Among the unwise regulations are mandated benefits, which are estimated to be responsible for as many as one in every four uninsured persons.

Many of the uninsured are healthy and can afford to purchase health insurance. The principal reason they are uninsured is that the premiums charged are too high relative to the value they place on being insured. The most important key to inducing them to buy insurance is to lower its price.

A barrier to low-cost health insurance is the lack of uniform regulations in all states. If small firms could buy AHP insurance with guaranteed uniform regulation, they could enjoy the same lower administrative costs now available to large company health plans that are federally regulated. AHPs would also be able to avoid mandated benefits and other complex, cost-increasing regulations that are imposed in different states.

In most of the United States, a few large firms dominate the health insurance marketplace and offer limited products to employers, their employees, individuals and the self-employed. These products meet the needs of some customers but not of many others. Given the size and diversity of the market, it is surprising how little diversity there is among insurance products.

Critics of AHPs would like to curtail their growth rather than expand it – principally by subjecting AHP insurance to the state regulations that apply to all other commercial health insurance. However, the answer to insuring the uninsured is not to limit competition, but to increase it. By making AHPs more competitive, we can lower the cost of insurance to small employers, their employees and the self-employed.

[page]

Table I - Total Population%2C Number Uninsured%2C Percent Uninsured for the Entire Year of 2001

"More than 41 million Americans are uninsured."

Depending on the point of view, America is facing a health care apocalypse, a health care crisis, or just "frictional dislocations" of health resources (Chollet and Kirk, 1998; Boushey et al., 2001). For those who are fortunate enough to work in a large firm, who have high incomes, and who have generous health plans, there is no crisis at all. For those who work in moderate-size firms, who have average incomes and limited choices among health plans with lower lifetime benefits, longer waiting periods, higher monthly premiums, and other restrictions, there is a health care crisis (Acs, 2001). For those who are underinsured or who are not insured at all, there is a health care apocalypse (Taylor, 2002; Blendon, 1999; De Posada, 2002).

Politicians in a position to affect public policy are typically focused somewhat narrowly (Litow, 2002; Nelson, 2002). They are usually caught in the crosscurrents of pressures to do what is right and to do what existing resources allow. Their actions are heavily influenced by their environment – close friends or neighbors who are disabled or whom they perceive to have been wronged by the system, political and social groups with whom they have intimate ties, and other channels from which they regularly receive information. This study is written in part to add to their perspectives.

Employer-Based Health Insurance. The American health care system is largely an employer-based system. After World War II, employers found that offering a health care plan was a way to attract employees (Bean and McFadden, 2000). Medium- and large-size employers began offering very basic benefits, typically as indemnity plans.

Health benefits were a powerful recruiting tool, and employers offering them enjoyed a significant competitive edge in the labor market. Labor unions increasingly saw them as a non-taxed alternative to taxable wages. The result was that employer-provided health care plans flourished with little regulation at any level of government.

Government Regulation. As employer-provided health plans became widespread, government at various levels began to intrude. Politicians and special interests began to grasp the potential to shift health care responsibilities and costs from the government to employers (Wilson, 2000). Society began to view employer-provided health care plans as an employer responsibility rather than an employment benefit (Westerfield, 1991). In time, government regulation became an important factor in determining the type of health insurance to which Americans had access. As we shall see, the unintended consequence of increasing government regulations was the creation of forces that increased the numbers of people without health insurance.

"The uninsured are predominantly healthy 18-to-34-year-olds with modest or low incomes."

Who Are the Uninsured? As Table I shows, the Census Bureau estimates that more than 41 million Americans are uninsured (Levitt et al., 2000; Levitt et al., 2002). Who are they? They are predominantly young, healthy people with modest or low income.

Table I shows that people between ages 18 and 34 account for slightly over 60 percent of the uninsured by age. The male portion of this group is typically healthy and optimistic and prefers cash compensation to other benefits. Although this is the prime age for females to start families, professional women tend to forgo childbearing until later in life when their careers are well established and their financial status has improved.

"About one-quarter of people with incomes less than $25,000 per year do not have health insurance."

Roughly one-quarter of people with incomes of less than $25,000 per year do not have health insurance. By contrast, among those who earn $75,000 or above, the percentage without insurance is 7.7 percent. Further, 62 percent of the uninsured are under the age of 35. Only 20 percent are over the age of 44. Annual health expenditure is far lower in young populations than in those nearing or at retirement (Fronstin, 2001). Moreover, 74.1 percent of the uninsured rate their health status as "excellent," "very good" or "good" (Brown et al., 2002).

One of the reasons why people in the lower-income categories are not covered is that they are healthy and do not believe they need insurance, or at least they do not believe it is worth what it costs. Young, healthy and low-income are precisely the characteristics of people who are highly sensitive to the price of insurance. As a consequence, people with these characteristics tend to be the ones most adversely affected by public policies that raise insurance premiums and most positively affected by policies that lower premiums.

Notice also from Table I that more than 90 percent of uninsured adults have some attachment to the workforce. This means that public policies that make it easier for employers to provide insurance to their employees have a potential to substantially reduce the number of uninsured.

Are Association Health Plans the Answer? In general, health insurance sold in the marketplace is regulated by state governments. However, about half of the people with private health insurance obtain it from an employer that is self-insured and is exempt from state regulation (Kaiser, 2002). These exempt plans fall under regulations enforced by the Department of Labor.1 As a result, a large company with employees in every state can rely on uniform, nationwide rules instead of confronting the disparate regulations of 50 separate states. Moreover, as a practical matter, only large companies can self-insure.

Association Health Plans (AHPs) are plans created for individuals and groups who belong to associations. For example, the National Association for the Self-Employed (NASE) makes AHP insurance available to its members throughout the country. NASE insurance is typically subject to some of the same state regulations as other insurers but is exempt from other regulations. AHP insurance may be thought of as a third kind of insurance, and the potential for growth of this insurance is quite large – given a favorable regulatory climate. For example, the National Restaurant Association could potentially offer AHP insurance to restaurant employees in all 50 states, and the National Rifle Association could potentially offer insurance to its members.

"Association Health Plans have the potential to insure the uninsured."

There are about 15,000 associations in the United States. Many of these are job- or career-related. Many others are related to hobbies or interests. For example, among the largest associations is the American Association of Retired People (AARP), which collects dues from about 35 million members and provides services in return. One of those services is supplemental medical insurance for seniors enrolled in Medicare. Although most associations do not offer health insurance, the potential is there. Some 6 million Americans are insured through associations and the number is growing (Matthews, 2002).

Proponents of AHPs argue that they have great potential to insure the uninsured. If AHPs could operate under uniform, nationwide regulations, they would be able to offer individuals and small businesses some of the same cost-cutting advantages now available only to large businesses. Accordingly, some proposals in Congress would allow AHPs to be chartered under federal law and avoid many state regulations. Other proposals would allow an AHP chartered in any one state to sell insurance in the other 49 states, abiding only by the regulations in its home state.2 Critics of AHPs would like to curtail their growth rather than expand it – principally by subjecting AHP insurance to the state regulations that apply to all other commercial health insurance (Terhune, 2002 a, b).

This study carefully considers these issues and concludes that AHPs have a significant potential to solve a major social problem: insuring the uninsured by providing lower-cost products more likely to meet the needs of those who have been priced out of the market for other health insurance.

[page]

Exhibit I - Market Concentration Criteria

In most of the United States, a few large firms dominate the health insurance marketplace. Moreover, these insurers tend to offer a limited product range to employers and their employees, as well as to individuals and the self-employed. While the products may meet the needs of some customers, they do not meet the needs of many others. In fact, given the size and diversity of the market, it is surprising how little diversity there is among the insurance products offered.

Large employers can negotiate health care plans with insurers on a bilateral basis, where the bargaining strengths of the insurer and the employer are more even. Small firms and individuals are more likely to be "price takers," with little ability to affect the price or composition of a health care plan. Their options are either to accept the package at the offered price or have no package at all (Koehler, 2002; Wilson, 2002). The only way individuals and small firms can increase their bargaining power, and hence their range of choices, is to join with others as members of a group or an association that can bargain with an insurer on the basis of more comparable strength.

The inequality of bargaining positions makes it difficult for individuals and small employers to obtain an attractive health plan at a favorable rate (Milam, 2002). Small employers report that insurers offer plans that have high rates, high deductibles, long waiting periods, and inflexible provisions (Manzullo, 2002). Lacking a range of insurance alternatives, the small employer must choose an unattractive plan, offer employees some other (less desirable) employee benefit, or pay higher (taxable) wages instead.

Exhibit II - Concentration Ratios and Their Market Structures

"It is difficult for individuals and small employers to obtain attractive health plans at favorable rates."

Measuring the Degree of Competition: Herfindahl-Hirshman Index. We introduce the concept of the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index (HHI) with a short anecdote about the Microsoft merger plans with Intuit, given as a student question in Baye's Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Baye, 2000):

In April 1995 the nightly news and newspapers across the world reported that the U.S. Justice Department filed suit to block software giant Microsoft's planned acquisition of financial software maker Intuit. Estimated reports placed Microsoft's share of the personal finance software market at about 20 percent, compared with Intuit's 70 percent share.

After spending over $4 million on merger plans, Microsoft announced in May 1995 that it had decided to call off the merger. In light of the dynamic nature of the software industry, Microsoft did not want to be tied up in a lengthy legal battle. In addition to the lost $4 million, Microsoft paid Intuit over $40 million for calling off the deal.

…the Justice Department generally challenges mergers when the relevant Herfindahl-Hirshman index is greater than 1,800 and the resulting increase in the index as a result of the merger is more than 100. Based on the reported market shares of Microsoft and Intuit, the Herfindahl-Hirshman index for the personal finance software market was at least 5,300 before the proposed merger, and would have increased to at least 8,100 after the merger. Thus, it seems that Microsoft should have realized that the Justice Department would attempt to block the merger. Spending $4 million attempting to justify the merger on technological or efficiency grounds was a gamble that did not pay off for Microsoft.

Table II - Concentration in the Market for HMOs

"A few large firms dominate the health insurance market-place."

The Herfindahl-Hirshman index is simple to calculate and is often used as a yardstick to indicate the competitiveness of a market (O'Sullivan and Sheffrin, 2001; Boyes and Melvin, 2002; Baye, 2000). For example, it is used as a measure of industry/market concentration before and after a proposed merger (Coate and Langenfield, 1993), as in the Microsoft case above. The contrast of the market positions of the insurers versus individuals and small employers is stark. The insurer market is highly concentrated, with only a few small firms serving niche markets. The U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) have jointly issued guidelines for horizontal mergers (Coate and Langenfield, 1993) that are used as regulatory measures of industry concentration. The guidelines state in part:3

… in some circumstances, where only a few firms account for most of the sales of a product, those firms can exercise market power, perhaps even approximating the performance of a monopolist, by either explicitly or implicitly coordinating their actions. Circumstances also may permit a single firm, not a monopolist, to exercise market power through unilateral or non-coordinated conduct – conduct the success of which does not rely on the concurrence of other firms in the market or on coordinated responses by those firms. In any case, the result of the exercise of market power is a transfer of wealth from buyers to sellers or a misallocation of resources.

Table III - Number of Carriers%2C Largest Carrier and Market Share Data for Small Group Health Insurance Carriers%2C by State

Note that the existence of only a few firms in a market does not always mean resources are being misallocated, especially if potential entrants into the market stand ready to meet unmet consumer needs. However, such competition for the market is unlikely to produce the desired outcome if there are artificial barriers to entry. Put another way, the most important antidote for monopoly or near monopoly is ease of entry into the market by outside potential competitors.

As a tool for assessing the degree of market concentration, the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index (HHI) is a function of the number of firms in a market and their respective market shares (Gilligan, 2002; Hirschey and Pappas, 2000; Katz and Rosen, 1991). It is calculated by the following formula:

HHI = 10,000 [Σ(S1)2 ] = 10,000 [(Si)2 + (S2) 2 +(S3)2 + … + (Sn)2 ],

Where the Si represent market share of each of the firms. For example, a market consisting of four firms with market shares of 30 percent, 30 percent, 20 percent and 20 percent has an HHI of 10,000 x (.3)2 + (.3)2 + (.2)2 + (.2)2 = 2600. In general, the HHI ranges from 10,000 (in the case of pure monopoly) to a number approaching zero (in the case of an atomistic market). Exhibit I shows how the index is used to judge whether the firms are highly concentrated in a given industry. Current market share data for specific insurers is not easily obtainable because it is not in the public domain. However, the formula is a useful measure of market concentration where the data are available.

"The antidote for monopoly is free entry into the market by competitors."

Measuring the Degree of Competition: The Four-Firm Concentration Ratio and Other Ratios. Another measure of market concentration is the Four-Firm Concentration Ratio. It is simply the sum of the respective market shares of the top four firms in a given industry for the area of interest. The formula is:

CR4 = S (Si) = S1 + S2 + S3 + S4,

where Si is the market share of the ith firm. Thus, in the example given above, the Four-Firm Concentration Ratio would be 100 percent.

Table II presents similar measures for four firms, eight firms, 20 firms and 50 firms. The four-firm ratio is most widely used, since it indicates a greater degree of clustering of firms. As an aid to interpreting the results, Exhibit II presents concentration ratios and their relationship to market structure.

Concentration in the Health Insurance Marketplace. A number of reliable sources of market share data are available from governmental agencies and research institutes.4 Table II shows the Census Bureau calculation of the share of the largest firms in the market for small group insurance. As the table shows, the largest four firms account for 65 percent of HMO business or a 65 percent market share that, according to most analysts, would be a strong oligopoly market structure. The table also shows that the eight largest firms account for almost all of the remaining market share.

Table III shows a state-by-state assessment of the small group market as of December 2002, by the General Accounting Office (GAO), based on reports from state insurance regulators. The GAO provided the following summary:

  • The median number of insurers in the small group market per state was 28, with a range from 4 in Hawaii to 77 in Indiana.
  • The median market share of the largest insurer was about 33 percent, with a range from about 14 percent in Texas to about 89 percent in North Dakota.
  • The five largest insurers, when combined, represented three-quarters or more of the market in 19 of 34 states supplying information, and they represented more than 90 percent in 7 of these states.
  • Twenty-five of 37 states supplying information identified a Blue Cross Blue Shield (BCBS) insurer as the largest organization offering health insurance in the small group market, and in all but one of the remaining 12 states a BCBS insurer was among the five largest.
  • The median market share of all the BCBS insurers in the 34 states supplying information was about 34 percent, with a range from about 3 percent in Vermont to about 89 percent in North Dakota; in 9 of these states BCBS carriers combined for half or more of the market.

Table III and Table IIIa is instructive in many ways. Simply put, there is a very high degree of market concentration in most states. In Oklahoma, Connecticut, Idaho, Maine, Maryland, North Dakota and Vermont, the largest five carriers have more than 90 percent of the total market share. The numbers also imply that the markets are concentrated, no matter how concentration is measured.5

"The largest insurer is often the only insurer, and its products are often offered on a 'take it or leave it' basis."

What the numbers do not show is perhaps the most important feature of health insurance markets: the impact of the largest carriers in geographic regions within states. Indeed, in many cities and towns the largest insurer is the only insurer (De Posada, 2002; Turner, 2002; Dressler, 1999). In these markets products are often offered on a "take it or leave it" basis. They may be overpriced, with benefits that do not fit the needs of many firms and many employees. With few or no alternatives, buyers must purchase an imperfect substitute for the type of insurance they prefer or forgo insurance altogether. For individuals and very small firms, the latter alternative is increasingly the alternative of choice (Tucker, 2003).

Barriers to Entry. The small group market, like the individual market, is highly concentrated on the insurer side and atomistic on the purchaser side. The result is that many needs go unmet. So why don't other insurers enter the market to meet these needs? The reason is the existence of many barriers to entry. Gerard Conway, of the Medical Society of the State of New York (Conway, 2001), gives some concrete examples:

For example, in order to be financially viable, health insurers need to develop sufficient business to permit the spreading of risk. In its challenge to the Aetna/Prudential merger, the Department of Justice noted that 'effective new entry for an HMO or HMO/POS plan in Houston or Dallas typically takes two to three years and costs approximately $50,000,000.'

Many insurance companies spend millions of dollars a year in local television and print ads, typically during employer 'open enrollment' seasons. In markets where a limited number of insurers already cover a large percentage of a market's population, it could take several years for a new health insurer to develop name and product recognition with purchasers and convince them to disrupt their current relationships with existing health insurers.

Health insurers also depend on a network of physicians, hospitals and health care providers. As the Department of Justice noted in the Aetna/Prudential merger, building a network can take years. In addition, exclusive contracts between existing insurers and providers can thwart or deter efforts by a new entrant to build a network.

All of these factors can operate as formidable barriers to entry for a new health insurance company trying to establish a foothold in a concentrated market, and even more so in the highly concentrated markets identified in this study.

The insurance company and its product are only one part of the competitive picture. Multiple tie-ins are both formal and informal. The tie-in between the health care provider network and the insurer, for example, is a significant barrier to entry.

"Large insurers use market power to negotiate lower rates with doctors and hospitals."

Every large managed care organization (MCO) has a development staff that negotiates with medical providers. Those that are included in the managed care network are listed in a directory as providers of choice for the MCO, and patients are referred to those providers. In a preferred provider organization (PPO), patients must pay more out of pocket for the service if their doctor is not listed as a recommended provider. In an exclusive provider organization (EPO), they must pay the entire amount out of pocket. The very existence of such networks of approved providers is a barrier to a new entrant, who has no established network.

Large insurers also use their market power to negotiate lower rates with doctors and hospitals than a smaller insurer or a new entrant can negotiate. The extent of this power was revealed in an eye-opening study by the Division of Governmental Affairs of the Medical Society of the State of New York (Conway, 2001). The Executive Summary of that study concludes:

With only one or a few HMOs in a region controlling all of the patient lives compared against thousands of individual health care providers who are legally prohibited from coming together to negotiate contracts with these dominant regional entities, the tremendous imbalance in market power becomes obvious.

This imbalance of power relegates the contracts that physicians and other providers must sign with the HMOs to those of contracts of adhesion: "take-it-or-leave-it" contracts that do not afford physicians and others any realistic opportunity to negotiate the terms therein.

"Large insurers with networks have information that small insurers and small AHPs do not."

Another powerful (maybe the most powerful) barrier to entry concerns the role of information about claims loss events and histories. In the property and casualty market it is a common practice to have up-to-date information that is well documented and is freely dispersed throughout the industry (Shaker and Gembicki, 1999). By contrast, health insurers hold loss experience as proprietary data and generally refuse to share it with any entity except their large corporate clients. Small insurers must purchase the information a few fragments at a time.

In every business, information is power. In health insurance, large insurers with networks have information that small insurers and small AHPs do not (Shaker and Gembicki, 1999; Fialka, 1997). This constitutes an enormous barrier to entry. [See the Case Study sidebar.]

[page]

Association Health Plans have the potential to make the market for health insurance more competitive and to help reduce the number of uninsured Americans.

Insuring the Uninsured by Creating More Insurance Options. The needs of small employers vary to some degree with the size of the firm and definitely by the composition of the firm's workforce. The one-size-fits-all packages often offered to small employers do not allow the employer to access a health plan that fits the particular needs of the firm's employees. The same is true in the market for individual insurance.

To address this problem, members of Congress (Bilirakis, 2002; Whitfield, 2002) as well as representatives of industry (Wilson, 2002) have noted the need for a health insurance market that is more responsive to individual purchasers, small businesses, and their employees.

Migrant workers have different workplace needs than do accountants. Construction firms with all-male crews have different needs than do all-female service workers. Different employers have special needs that require custom health plan options. Large insurers have typically not served these needs very well, nor have they been responsive to the changing circumstances of very small employers.

The potential to increase the number of healthy people who obtain insurance is indicated by the experience of Medical Savings Account (MSA) plans under the federal government's pilot program. These are high-deductible plans combined with a savings account (the MSA). Individuals who have such plans spend from their MSA and out of pocket until they reach the deductible, with the plan typically paying all costs above the deductible. Because people get to keep (in their MSA) all the funds they do not spend, they are rewarded for being prudent, careful buyers of health care. Evidence shows that MSA plans significantly increase the perceived value of health insurance for healthy, uninsured people. In fact, the Internal Revenue Service recently estimated that 73 percent of all the people who have obtained an MSA plan were previously uninsured. Currently only about 100,000 people are enrolled in tax-favored MSA plans (Internal Revenue Service, 2002). The spread of these plans has been delayed by cumbersome restrictions and regulations, but their success to date illustrates the tremendous untapped potential of allowing the market to meet consumer needs in innovative ways.

"AHPs would give small firms the bargaining power of large companies."

AHPs would also afford small firms the economies of scale and bargaining power that large companies now enjoy (Fletcher, 2002). This is important because the Department of Labor estimates that six of 10 Americans without health insurance are in families headed by someone working for a small business (Chao, 2002). As Rep. John Boehner, Chairman of the Subcommittee on Employer-Employee Relations of the U.S. House of Representatives (Boehner, 1999), points out:

AHPs allow small employers and the self-employed to band together voluntarily in associations to form multiple employer groups. Under this concept, these large groups could self-insure or fully insure, gaining all of the advantages of pooling including greater economies of scale and lower costs. The result could be a 'rising tide that lifts all boats.' Small employers who now cannot afford coverage could offer it to their uninsured workers. States may benefit by having fewer people on Medicaid or dependent on state high-risk pools.

Insuring the Uninsured by Lowering the Cost of Basic Insurance. As noted above, many of the uninsured are healthy and can afford to purchase health insurance. The principal reason they are uninsured is that the premiums charged are too high relative to the value they place on being insured. The most important key to inducing them to become insured is to lower the price of insurance. There are three principal reasons why healthy people have been priced out of the market. As explained below, Association Health Plans offer a partial solution for all three.

First, in most health insurance markets the healthy are overcharged so that the sick can be undercharged. In some cases this occurs because it reflects the traditional pricing philosophy of such organizations as Blue Cross Blue Shield (Goodman, 1980). In other cases, state law effectively creates cross-subsidies and cost shifting.6 In either case, there are two bad consequences: (1) the healthy who are overcharged respond by underinsuring or by not buying insurance at all, and (2) the sick who are undercharged overinsure – thus driving up the average cost of insurance even more.

Second, guaranteed issue laws in the small group market (in every state) and in individual markets (in a few states) force insurers to take all comers, regardless of health status. This means that people can avoid costly premiums while they are healthy, secure in the knowledge that they can buy insurance for a reasonable price after they get sick. Of course, as more healthy people act on this incentive, the remaining pool of people who are insured at any point in time will become sicker and therefore more costly.

Third, regulatory burdens discussed below increase the cost of insurance, and these burdens have a larger impact on the individual market and on small firms than they have on large firms.

Association Health Plans cannot solve all these problems. They do have the potential to avoid some of the costs, however. They also have the potential to lower other costs. By one estimate, small employers pay 18 percent more for health insurance than large employers (Fletcher, 2002). By allowing small and large employers to purchase insurance in much the same way, AHPs can reduce that difference.

Overall, small employers (and their employees) are the first to be priced out of the market by cost increases, and they will be the first area of expansion if those costs can be lowered (Turner, 2002).

"There are more than 1,000 health insurance mandates among the 50 states."

Insuring the Uninsured by Avoiding Costly Mandated Benefits. Mandated health insurance benefits are state regulations that require insurers to cover specific services and specific providers. Currently, there are more than 1,000 such mandates among the 50 states. Mandates cover services ranging from acupuncture to in vitro fertilization, from mental health care to cosmetic surgery. They cover providers ranging from chiropractors to naturopaths. They cover bone marrow transplants in New Jersey, clinical trials in Virginia, hairpieces in Minnesota, marriage counseling in Connecticut, and pastoral counseling in Maine (Laudicina, Losleben and, Walker, 2001).

In many cases, benefits mandated by state governments are already included in the richer health plans of larger employers. These benefits often would not have been included in plans sold in the individual and small group markets, however, because buyers in the latter markets would typically prefer lower premiums in order to acquire basic coverage (Mills, 2002; Baumgardner, 2000). Mandated benefits in these markets create additional costs that must be borne by those who have no market power or negotiating clout.

"Mandated benefits price healthy people out of the market."

Mandated benefits raise the cost of insurance and price otherwise healthy people out of the market. In fact, studies estimate that as many as one out of every four uninsured Americans has been priced out of the health insurance market because of mandates (Goodman and Musgrave, 1988; Jensen and Morrisey, 1999). The impact has been especially severe for small business (Keating, 2002; Close, 2002), for agricultural communities (Nelson, 2002), and for minority populations, including Hispanics (De Posada, 2002).

The author has reviewed scores of testimonies of employer groups, institutions, and specialists before both the U.S. House of Representatives and the U.S. Senate. The testimonies make compelling arguments regarding the heavy and unnecessary burden of state mandates. These are credible witnesses representing large sectors of our economy, especially small businesses. They are unanimous in their position that mandates cause great harm.

If mandates do so much harm, then why do they exist? Very few mandates have been enacted because of patient pressure. Almost all are the result of the lobbying power of special interest providers, including doctor groups. Nevertheless, in an unexpected but welcome move, an American Medical Association study (Carpenter, 2002) indicated support for AHPs and for exemption from state mandates, premium taxes, and small group rating laws. The report states, in part:

Therefore, the AMA supports federal legislation enabling the formation of alternative means of pooling risk in order to increase individual choice of coverage and cost consciousness. Some alternative prototypes already exist in the form of association health plans (AHPs), consumer-directed health care arrangements, and some Internet-based health insurance companies. In addition, the AMA supports legislation allowing individuals to "buy in" to state employee purchasing pools … Businesses are increasingly interested in AHPs as a way to control costs and [in] consumer-directed health care options as a way to allow their employees to control their own health care decisions. In addition, creative alternative insurance pools would be encouraged by exempting them from selected state regulations regarding mandated benefits, premium taxes and small group rating laws, while safeguarding state and federal patient protection laws. [Emphasis added.]

There is no question that most state mandates are beneficial to specific persons for specific situations. The paramount question is whether they should be forced on others. Small employers could offer bare-bones packages or plans with minimal state mandates that satisfy the basic needs of employees and are affordable. Such benefits as drug rehabilitation, mental health care, and treatments for chronic ailments or long-term disabilities could be covered in a supplement to an employer-provided plan and paid for by the employees on an optional basis.

Small employers should be concentrating on making a quality product at a reasonable price. It is unrealistic to expect them to also function as a "mini insurance company" on site to serve the social welfare functions demanded by special interests and the government. The choice of benefits, however, should be the prerogative of the employer and the employees or of the employer acting as agent for the employees.

In order to serve the needs of purchasers of insurance, the Department of Labor should encourage AHPs to design plans with basic major medical benefits and few or none of the special benefits currently mandated by the states. AHPs could use a managed care network with limited access to specialists, reasonable and appropriate waiting periods for qualification, and affordable monthly premiums (lower than premiums for individual coverage outside the group). Alternatively, they could provide an indemnity plan with a fee schedule and lower the costs even further. They also could take a Medical Savings Account approach. Such plans could be designed to attract relatively healthy young workers. The AHPs' ability to avoid costly state mandates and sell lower-priced insurance to healthy uninsured people would help overcome much of the damage caused by unwise regulation.

"AHPs can sell lower-priced insurance to healthy uninsured people."

Insuring the Uninsured by Avoiding Other Regulatory Burdens. Unnecessary state regulations add costs to employer health plans, and they may add legal fees and administration costs. This is especially true for small employers (Langer, 2002), who often must hire consultants to ensure compliance with the sometimes conflicting state and federal regulations. AHPs would have state regulation preemption, thus resulting in savings significant enough to make the difference between affording and not affording a health plan. [See the sidebar on the Small Business Administration report.]

For example, state regulations that require prior rate approval are costly and time-consuming and are often administered unfairly and unwisely. Rate hearings may last six to nine months and require that the insurer be represented at least by an attorney and often by specialists in order to present an effective case before the administrative judge or regulatory agency. This often results in opportunities lost and restrictions on the management of resources. AHP preemption from this type of regulation would yield significant savings, which could be passed along to the firm's employees. It would allow the insurer to respond quickly to changing circumstances, controlled by competition and market forces rather than by a political body.

"Regulation often gives larger companies a competitive advantage over smaller companies."

Regulations also burden such large insurers as Blue Cross Blue Shield. However, large insurers may oppose unwise regulation less vigorously and may even perceive it as a source of competitive advantage. John Graham, Administrator, Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs, Office of Management and Budget, explains it this way:

Large corporations… oftentimes see regulation as an opportunity to raise capital costs for participants in an industry and to create entry barriers for new companies into those businesses.

That leads to the key finding of the Crain/Hopkins Report commissioned by the Small Business Administration. Firms with less than 20 employees face 60 percent larger regulatory burdens per employee than firms with greater than 500 employees. So I think it is important to realize that… larger companies, in certain circumstances… see [regulation] as a competitive advantage relative to small companies. [Emphasis added.]

Insuring the Uninsured by Avoiding the Costs of Unfair Taxes. AHPs would be preempted from taxes on the premiums of their health plans. Taxes on the premiums of individually purchased insurance and employer health plans are a source of general revenue for the states. Large self-funded employers and their employees do not pay this tax, nor do enrollees in Medicare and Medicaid, nor do state employees. Virtually the entire burden of the tax on health plan premiums falls on the most defenseless part of the market – where people pay the tax through higher premiums. The revenues from these taxes often go into the general revenue funds of the states and are spent on projects that have nothing to do with the health of the citizens. In other cases, the revenues are used to fund the state's high-risk pool. Even though the goal of the risk pool is to insure more people, the burden of accomplishing this socially important task is not shared equitably. The taxes are clearly a form of regulatory discrimination against individuals, the self-employed, and employers of small business.

The small employer joining an AHP would not be subject to the premium tax and would therefore be able to use those resources to hire more people and/or increase benefits to existing employees. With more affordable rates, more people would either purchase their own insurance or enroll in their small employer's health plan.

Expected Results. The case for offering lower-cost health plans to individuals, the self-employed and small business is strong. Perhaps the most important argument for AHPs is that millions of people who are not covered because of high costs or lack of availability would be able to obtain affordable coverage. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) analysis of legislation pending in Congress estimates that small businesses can expect to reap savings averaging between 9 percent and 25 percent of the cost of their health insurance premiums. As a result, the CBO estimates that 330,000 – and potentially as many as two million – of the currently uninsured would obtain health insurance (Baumgardner and Hagen, 2000).

"AHPs could insure approximately 4.5 million workers and dependents who are currently uninsured."

Some experts believe that the CBO study underestimated the number of persons without health insurance that would be covered if the Association Health Plan legislation is enacted (Wilson, 2000; Talent, 2000; Joensen, 2000). Mark Joensen of CONSAD Research Corporation estimates that the creation of Association Health Plans would result in an increase in employer-sponsored insurance coverage of approximately 2.3 million workers and 2.2 million dependents (Joensen, 2000).

[page]

With regard to Association Health Plans, the hundreds of pages of Capitol Hill testimony the author reviewed presented common messages and common arguments on each side. This section will examine some of the main arguments and seek to determine their relevance to reducing the uninsured in America.

Would AHPs Be Able to Unfairly Escape State-Mandated Benefits? Mandated benefit laws, as we have seen, force buyers of insurance to accept benefits they may not want and may not need. The laws increase the price of health insurance and make it more costly than it otherwise would be. As a result, many healthy people who are potential buyers of bare-bones insurance have been priced out of the market (Dressler, 1999; Wilson, 2000; Weil, 2000).

AHPs would avoid costly mandates and provide healthy people with affordable basic health insurance.

The answer to the question "Is it fair?" is "Fair to whom?" Certainly AHP insurance is fair to the uninsured who have been unfairly priced out the market. Is it fair to large insurers who currently dominate the markets and live under mandated benefit laws? Perhaps not, but two considerations are worth noting.

First, the primary social goal should be insuring the uninsured rather than making large insurers more comfortable. Forced to choose between the two, the needs of the uninsured should come first.

Second, between the two groups, large insurers are much better positioned to deal with the unfairness. For one thing, they already posses competitive advantages in the marketplace, as we have seen. For another, they are politically more powerful. Allowing AHPs to sell mandate-free insurance would undoubtedly put great pressure on state governments to extend this privilege to other insurers and the people who purchase their products. Large insurers would be welcome allies in this noble cause.

Would AHPs Be Able to Unfairly Escape Other Government Regulations? Private health insurance for most Americans is already exempted from regulation by state governments. However, those who buy state-regulated insurance face 50 separate regulatory regimes, with 50 different sets of laws, rules, processes, procedures, language requirements, and the like. In principle, a large company with employees in many states faces many sets of regulations. To free large employers from this potential regulatory nightmare was the goal of the Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA), which exempts firms that self-insure from state regulations. The ERISA preemption allows large companies to conduct business under regulations devised by the U.S. Department of Labor. Since regulation by the Department of Labor is uniform across state jurisdictions, this reduces the firm's legal and administrative costs.

"AHP insurance sold under uniform regulations would have lower administrative costs."

Unfortunately, as a practical matter the ERISA preemption is available only to large businesses. Firms with fewer than 50 employees are not in a position to self-insure. If small firms could buy AHP insurance sold under uniform regulations in all states, they could enjoy the same lower administrative costs now available to large companies. Lack of uniformity among the states with regard to laws and regulations is a problem for AHPs in the same way that it would be a problem for large firms, absent the ERISA preemption. Even if the laws on the books were the same, the 50 distinct insurance commissioners whose job is to interpret the laws each may interpret them in different ways.

There are several estimates of the potential cost savings. Donald Dressler, testifying to the House Committee on Education and the Workforce about insurance services provided to the Western Growers Association, estimated that uniform regulations across state lines would reduce administrative costs by as much as 30 percent (Dressler, 1999). A CONSAD study yielded a range of 5.4 percent to 22 percent (CONSAD 1998). Not long ago, the Congressional Budget Office estimated that the AHP legislation before Congress would reduce premiums for small businesses between 9 percent and 25 percent (Baumgardner and Hagen, 2000).

Lower administrative costs, of course, mean lower premiums and more people insured. By one estimate, there would be a gain of 200,000 additional insured for each percentage decrease in health care costs (Congressional Budget Office, 2000). CONSAD estimates that figure to be closer to 300,000 (CONSAD, 1998). The numbers vary, but the message is clear: lowering the costs of meeting regulatory burdens will lower the costs of health care plans, and that in turn will increase the number of insurers and the number of insured.

Is it fair to allow AHPs access to uniform federal regulation and not allow other insurers the same opportunity? Perhaps not, but large insurers have large legal departments and retain lawyers who specialize in state regulations. That infrastructure is already in place and has been for decades. To require AHPs to duplicate those resources in their infancy is irrational from an economic point of view, especially in light of the alternative of federal oversight by the Department of Labor.

"Uniform federal regulation would protect AHPs against hundreds of frivolous lawsuits."

Being under uniform federal regulation would protect AHPs against hundreds of frivolous potential lawsuits based on compliance with conflicting state regulations (Dressler, 1999; Turner, 2002; McIntosh, 2002). Having a uniform federal jurisdiction rather than 50 different jurisdictions drastically reduces the legal and organizational costs for small businesses, giving them the competitive advantage that large self-funded corporations have enjoyed for years.

Would AHPs Destabilize Insurance Markets? There are two issues here that are hard to separate. We will consider each in turn.

First, the existence of monopoly power is itself a market failure. Monopoly output is restricted compared to competitive output and monopoly prices are higher than competitive prices. The result is a social welfare loss (Amato, 1988; Bennefield, 1998; Canary, 2001; Gupta, 1994). Entry into the market is a way to correct that market failure – as competition lowers prices and expands output. What the dominant firm sees as destabilization, however, the new entrant and its customers see as competition. The status quo will, of course, be disturbed. The economic question is: Will people be better off?

Second, the small group market already suffers from instability, courtesy of unwise regulation. Because of state and federal laws, every state in the union has guaranteed-issue legislation requiring insurers to accept all comers, regardless of health status. Almost every state has some form of premium restriction as well (rate bands, community rating, etc.). These regulations keep the premiums artificially low for the sickest groups and artificially high for the healthiest.

As a consequence, small groups have an incentive to "game" the system. That is, they have an incentive to remain uninsured and avoid paying expensive premiums while everyone in the group is healthy, then immediately purchase insurance if a member of the group develops a serious illness. This activity causes the overall pool of people who are insured to be sicker than otherwise and contributes to the overall rise in the cost of insurance. Moreover, the more costly insurance becomes, the greater the incentive to game the system. The more serious version of this spiral is called a "death spiral," because with each iteration conditions get worse.

Mark Litow, representing the Council for Affordable Health Insurance, opened his testimony before the U.S. House Committee on Small Business with this observation (Litow, 2002):

The small group market is in very bad shape. That is so because of a continuing series of incentives… [that were] seriously exacerbated by the use of community rating or rating bands and guaranteed issue as implemented during the 1990s. These incentives have caused skyrocketing premiums in the market combined with a gradually decreasing proportion of eligible groups being insured.

Regulations are worse in some states than in others. Raymond Keating, Chief Economist, Small Business Survival Committee, testifying before the U.S. House Committee on Small Business, comments on the aftermath of community-rating and guaranteed-issue legislation by saying (Keating, 2002):

The results are completely predictable – much higher insurance costs, and fewer insured individuals. And that has been the case in the states that have imposed guaranteed issue and community rating.

For example, New Jersey imposed guaranteed issue in the individual market in legislation passed in 1994. From December 1994 to January 2002, among four insurers offering family coverage during this period, monthly premiums increased by 556 percent (Aetna), 344 percent (Blue Cross Blue Shield NJ), 612 percent (Metropolitan Life), and 471 percent (National Health Insurance).

In Kentucky, after the state adopted guaranteed issue and community rating in 1994, 45 insurers fled the state and premiums skyrocketed. Also in 1994, a similar scenario played out in New Hampshire in response to passing guaranteed issue and community rating.

"Ironically, state reforms have led to fewer people being insured."

Ironically, state reforms designed to make it easier for people to obtain health insurance more often than not have led to fewer people being insured. For example, a study by Schriver and Arnett (1998) concluded that the 16 states that had been most aggressive in regulating their health insurance markets through guaranteed issue, community rating, and other directives had uninsured rates that rose eight times faster than the 34 states that were less regulatory. Wayne Nelson of Communicating for Agriculture and the Self-Employed explained the consequences in testimony before the House Committee on Small Business (Nelson, 2002):

Many of the federal and state reforms that were enacted in the 1990s with the intent of helping the small group market have backfired and actually done harm. Also, several states have tried reforms in the individual market, tried to make them more like the employer market with disastrous results. Some state legislatures believe[d] that simply legislating that every insurance company had to offer insurance to anyone at any time, regardless of their medical conditions, could really solve the problem. And this has led to sky-high premiums and no competition, with many companies leaving states that have guaranteed issue in the individual market. [Emphasis added.]

"In the United States, we are making it easy for people to get insurance after they get sick."

In the United States, we are making it increasingly easy for people to get insurance after they get sick. As a consequence, they have no reason to buy insurance while they are healthy. Increasingly, there is no relationship between the premium charged and the risk transferred by those who pay that premium.

Such a market is inherently unstable. Moreover, virtually any self-interested act by any participant in the market is likely to add to that instability. The answer is not to limit competition. The answer is to change the regulations that cause the instability in the first place.

Do AHPs Unfairly Compete by Engaging in Risk Selection? Closely related to the issue of stability is the issue of risk selection. Critics maintain that AHPs will use unfair methods of risk selection. By this they usually mean that AHPs will "cherry pick" and seek good risks while avoiding bad risks. What critics rarely acknowledge is that there is no such thing as a good risk or a bad risk independent of price. What the term "good risk" means is someone who is paying a premium substantially greater than the expected costs of that person's health care. In other words, a good risk is someone who is profitable because he or she is being overcharged. Conversely, "bad risks" are people who are charged less than the cost of their care. Accordingly, these people are unprofitable.

The business of insurance is the business of pricing and managing risk. Competition in the insurance marketplace tends to ensure that risk is priced accurately. Thus in a competitive market, every new person in a plan will tend to be charged a premium that reflects the expected costs of that person's health care at the time of entry into the plan.

New entrants into almost any market seek to sell to the most profitable customers. The reason these customers are profitable is that they are being overcharged by the insurers already in the market. In seeking to better meet the needs of these customers and give them a better deal, new entrants should be regarded as heroes and encouraged to provide the best, lowest-cost, richest product they can. In any normal market, that is exactly the way they would be viewed. However, in health insurance the tradition is to scorn new entrants for "cherry picking." Yet cherry picking is nothing more than trying to satisfy consumer needs better than a rival. Moreover, the dominant insurers routinely practice various forms of cherry picking. For example, segmenting the market by client demographics is cherry picking. Insuring certain market segments and not insuring others or refusing to write policies in a given market or state is cherry picking. In fact, many large insurers built their businesses in this way.

The foundation concepts of underwriting are risk measurement, risk assessment, risk selection, and risk classification. The largest underwriting departments are found in the largest insurance companies and for good reason. Underwriting and risk pricing is exactly what an insurance company is supposed to do. Rates charged for health benefit packages must be approved by the underwriting department, based on risk measurement, sophisticated actuarial models, and predictive risk assessment. When an insurer excludes certain individuals or firms from a plan, the decision is made based on risk selection, which enables the insurer to offer a more competitive product at a lower cost to the risk pool it chooses.

"Many major health insurers have withdrawn from the small group market and from the individual market."

Many major health insurers have withdrawn from the small group market and from the individual market in various states. When an insurer quits writing business in a state, it exercises the ultimate risk selection technique – avoiding the market altogether. Short of leaving the market, large insurers select risks in other ways. Do they take any person or group irrespective of their state of health and without waiting periods? No. The prospective subscriber must meet certain underwriting requirements before being covered. For example, insurers usually refuse to insure a group unless at least 75 percent (the minimum "group participation ratio") of employees who are eligible enroll in the plan. As a result, a small group in which a significant number of employees choose not to participate will be refused insurance. Insurers will also refuse to insure a group if the employer does not pay a certain share of the premium (usually 50 percent or more). All of these practices involve risk selection. All are designed to attract healthier and avoid less-healthy groups.

It is likely that AHPs will use the same underwriting techniques to fashion health care plans that suit the needs of their membership. They may even contract with a large insurance underwriter to assist in the design and delivery of benefit plans that fit their needs. There is no credible evidence that the AHPs will engage in more selection activities than do existing insurers.

Would AHPs Avoid Socially Desirable Cross-Subsidies? The view that the goal of insurance companies is to measure, assess, price and manage risk is not universally held. Some would like to use the private health insurance system to achieve a sort of private sector socialism in which insurers take from those who are healthy in order to give to those who are sick. Mary Nell Lehnhard, representing Blue Cross Blue Shield (Lehnhard, 2002), expressed this view when she said:

To address wide variations in premiums charged to particular groups based on health status, all states adopted risk-spreading requirements that assured cross-subsidization between low- and high-cost groups. These rules set limits on what an insurer could charge its sickest group compared to its healthiest group (both within a single product and across all products offered by the insurer). Insurers are now forced to pool all their business; this assures cross-subsidies and prevents insurers from pricing their products in a manner that avoids high-cost small employers.

"There must be imperfections in the market in order for cross-subsidies to exist."

In order for one group to serve as a source of cross-subsidy for another group, however, there must be imperfections in the marketplace. Competitive markets do not have cross-subsidies because competition insures that each buyer is charged a price that reflects the expected cost of services he or she consumes.

For one group to subsidize another for any reason means that one group is paying too much and the other is paying too little (Boyes and Melvin, 2002; O'Sullivan and Sheffrin, 2001). It is easy to understand how a large, dominant firm has the capacity to cross-subsidize among client bases, since economies of scale and scope afford the firm excess or redundant resources. It is not easy to understand why that philosophy should be imposed on everyone else.

Would AHPs Siphon Off the Healthiest Customers at the Expense of the Sick? This issue is closely related to the previous one. We list it separately in order to draw attention to some special problems in the small group market. Mary Nell Lehnhard explains the Blue Cross Blue Shield position this way (Lehnhard, 2002):

… what we are concerned about is that AHPs will raise the cost for our small employer pools by making it very attractive for healthier groups to leave the pools, whether it is us or another insurance company, and join an AHP where there are no mandated benefits, and they do not need those benefits. The people who need the benefits would stay with the state-insured pools and make the costs go up for those sicker small groups.

Notice again the implicit assumption that healthy groups should subsidize the sicker groups. The tacit goal is to overcharge the group that has fewer claims so that the group that incurs the higher claims can be undercharged. In other words, BCBS is arguing that healthy people should be forced to pay a higher premium for their health plans in order to support or subsidize the less-healthy people. This is another way of saying that healthy employees should be penalized for their good health and the unhealthy rewarded for their bad health.

In fact, there is a problem in the small group market. However, that problem is not caused by unfair competition, and it will not be solved by suppressing competition.

"The structure of the smaller group market is not the result of normal market forces."

We noted above that the market for small group insurance today is in most respects dysfunctional. One sign of that dysfunction is that small firms cannot buy the kind of health insurance that is routinely sold in the individual market. For example, when an individual buys insurance he or she is guaranteed the right to remain in the insurance pool indefinitely. Each year, premiums are likely to increase, but they increase the same percent for everyone in the pool. Those whose health condition has worsened cannot be kicked out or singled out for special premium increases.

Once insured, each person in the pool is treated the same and premium increases are the same for all, regardless of subsequent health history. This is the true meaning of the concept of insurance. Once in the pool, premiums for the ill and unhealthy increase no faster than for the healthy.

Things are very different in the market for small group insurance, where people generally cannot stay in an insurance pool for more than a year. At the end of the year, the small firm and its employees are kicked out of the pool, re-rated on the basis of changes in its employees' health status, and allowed to reenter the pool only if they pay the new rates. Firms with employees who develop costly illnesses are forced to pay higher premiums the following year precisely because some have become ill.

Another sign of dysfunction is asymmetry in the market contract. Basically, at the end of a one-year insurance period, the insureds can leave one insurer and give their patronage to another. The reverse is not true. Because of guaranteed issue, the insurer cannot leave the insured by refusing to renew the group. If both sides of the market were allowed to sign longer-term contracts, stability would be greatly enhanced.

The structure of the small group market is not the result of normal market forces. It is the result of unwise regulation. The solution to the problems in this market is to reform the unwise regulations, not to stifle competition.

Would AHPs Make Fraud, Insolvency and Abuse More Likely? Critics assert that the Department of Labor (DOL) has inadequate experience and resources to monitor AHPs and prevent fraud, insolvency and abuse. What the critics overlook is that the DOL already oversees 2.5 million job-based health plans, covering 131 million workers, retirees and their families (Chao, 2003). Put another way, most of the people with private health insurance in the United States already rely on the DOL for oversight and appear to be no worse off for the experience.

"The Department of Labor oversees 2.5 million job-based health plans, covering 131 million workers, retirees and their families."

One source of concern regarding the formation of Association Health Plans has been the increasing number of allegations of fraud and abuse by the Multiple Employer Welfare Arrangements (MEWAs). The MEWA is an association-type arrangement similar to the Association Health Plan but distinct from it structurally and legally; it does not meet the ERISA definition of an employee benefit plan and is not certified by the U.S. Department of Labor. It may be regulated by states. MEWAs that are fully insured and certified must meet only broad state insurance laws regulating their reserves.

[page]

Based on a review of the technical literature and the testimony of scores of witnesses before the U.S. House of Representatives and the U.S. Senate, as well as first-hand experience in the field for about 20 years, this author draws a number of conclusions with regard to Association Health Plans and their position in the political arena and in the marketplace.

  • The market for health insurance is dominated by a few large insurers in most states, and in some cities and towns there is only one insurer.
  • While these large insurers may meet the needs of many customers, often they do not meet the needs of individuals and small businesses.
  • It is difficult for rivals to enter the health insurance marketplace in most states because of national barriers to entry as well as artificial barriers created by unwise state regulations.
  • Most of the uninsured tend to be young and healthy, have low to moderate incomes, and be especially sensitive to the price of insurance.
  • Most of the uninsured are connected to the workplace, and most uninsured workers are employees of small businesses.
  • Small businesses are especially burdened by the lack of competition and by unwise regulations.
  • Among the unwise regulations, state-mandated health insurance benefits are estimated to cause as many as one in every four uninsured persons to be without health insurance.
  • Guaranteed issue requirements, community rating, and other restrictions on underwriting also make things worse by causing the sick to overinsure and the healthy to underinsure and by destabilizing the small group market.
  • By uniting many small firms with similar interests across the country, AHPs potentially could take full advantage of economies of scale and lower health care costs for their members.
  • Costs would be further lowered because AHPs would be able to function under one uniform set of federal regulations rather than 50 sets of state regulations.
  • AHPs would be able to avoid mandated benefits and the other complex, cost-increasing regulations imposed in different states.
  • AHPs have the potential to insure millions of people who are currently uninsured.

"AHPs could lower small business insurance costs by as much as 25 percent."

No one can predict the exact effects of the expansion of AHPs into the health insurance marketplace. Estimates are that AHPs, operating under federal law, could lower small business insurance costs by as much as 25 percent. Estimates of the number of additional people who would obtain health insurance range as high as 4.5 million.

This is why AHP legislation is a high priority for the Bush administration. As Department of Labor Secretary Elaine Chao explained:

The president has made affordable and accessible health insurance for small businesses a priority of this administration. By banding together to leverage their purchasing power, Association Health Plans will enable small companies to obtain health insurance on terms similar to those now enjoyed by large firms, establishing an important new way to lower costs and expand coverage.

NOTE: Nothing written here should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views of the National Center for Policy Analysis or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Congress.  

[page]
  1. The plans fall under the provisions of the Employee Retirement and Income Security Act (ERISA) of 1974.
  2. In all versions, AHPs would be subject to the provisions of the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act (HIPAA), which among other things makes health insurance "guaranteed issue" in the small group market.
  3. "Horizontal Merger Guidelines," U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, Washington, D.C., April 2, 1992.
  4. They are usually derived by stating a firm's market share as a percentage of the total receipts for a given NAICS (North American Industry Classification System) code. One such source is the U.S. Census Bureau (USCB) Health Care & Social Assistance – Subject Series, Table 6a. "Concentration by Largest Firms Subject to Federal Income Tax: 1997" and Table 6b. For those firms that are not subject to federal income tax, it contains information regarding the number of establishments, receipts – amount and percent of total, annual payroll, first quarter payroll, and number of paid employees. This study uses the NAICS codes for industry number 62 and its respective subcategories. Table 3.1 in the text was adapted from USCB Table 6a.
  5. For example, when the top five firms represent 90 percent of the market, the Four-Firm Concentration Ratio is at least 72 percent and the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index is at least 1,296.
  6. Some states have passed laws mandating insurance rate bands, whereby insurers are limited in their ability to charge rates based on actuarial risk. For instance, such laws might mandate that the sickest individuals cannot be charged more than 50 percent more than the average rate and the healthiest cannot be charged less than 50 percent of the average rate. Grouping people with diverse actuarial risks in more closely banded pools results in a cross-subsidy, whereby the young and healthy are charged more than the expected cost of their care so that older or less-healthy individuals can pay less than the expected cost of their care.
[page]

Acs, Gregory. (2001) "How a Changing Workforce Affects Employer-Sponsored Health Insurance," Health Affairs 20:1 (Jan/Feb):178-83.

Allen, Kathryn. Personal letter to Sen. Christopher Bond, transmitting "Table 1, Number of Carriers, Largest Carrier, and Market Share Data for Small Group Health Insurance Carriers, by State," March 25, 2002. [Provided to Author.]

Amato, Louis and Ronald Wilder. (1988) "Market Concentration, Efficiency, and Antitrust Policy: Demsetz Revisited," Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics 27:4 (Autumn):3-19.

Arth, Raymond. Testimony on "The Cost of Regulation to Small Business" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., June 6, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Baker, Laurence. (2000) "HMO Market Penetration and Costs of Employer-Sponsored Health Plans," Health Affairs 19:5 (Sep/Oct):121-28.

Baumgardner, James and Stuart Hagen. (2000) "Increasing Small-Firm Health Insurance Coverage through Association Health Plans and Healthmarts," Congressional Budget Office, January, Washington, D.C.

Baye, Michael. (2000) Managerial Economics & Business Strategy 3rd ed. Boston: Irwin McGraw-Hill.

Beam, Burton and John McFadden. (2000) Employee Benefits 6th ed. Chicago: Real Estate Education Company.

Bennefield, Robert. (1998) "Who Loses Coverage and for How Long?" Current Population Reports, P70-64, U.S. Census Bureau, August, Washington, D. C.

Berman, Erika. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Healthcare" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., July 9, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Bilirakis, Michael. Testimony on "The Uninsured and Affordable Health Care Coverage" before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-98. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 28, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Blendon, Robert. (1999) "The Uninsured, the Working Uninsured, and the Public," Health Affairs 18:6 (Nov/Dec):203-11.

Blue Cross and Blue Shield of Montana v. Max D. Agather and Larry Managhan, Montana 1st Dist. Ct., Lewis and Clark Co., Order, BDV 97-181, August 18, 1999.

Blumberg, Linda and Len Nichols. (2001) "The Health Status of Workers Who Decline Employer-Sponsored Insurance," Health Affairs 20:6 (Nov/Dec):180-87.

Boehner, John. Testimony on "Expanding Affordable Health Care Coverage: Benefits and Consequences of Association Health Plans" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 106 Cong. 2nd Sess., March 25, 1999, Washington, D.C.

Boushey, Heather. (2001) "Last Hired, First Fired: Job Losses Plague Former TANF Recipients." Economic Policy Institute, Washington, D.C.

Boushey, Heather. Testimony on "The Needs of the Working Poor: Helping Working Families Make Ends Meet" before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, February 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Boushey, Heather et al. (2001) "Hardships in America: The Real Story of Working Families." Economic Policy Institute, Washington, D.C.

Boyes, William and Michael Melvin. (2002) Microeconomics 5th ed. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

Brauns, Ryan. Testimony before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., August 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Brown, E. Richard et al. (2002) The State of Health Insurance in California: Findings from the 2001 California Health Interview Survey. UCLA Center for Health Policy Research, Los Angeles, Calif.

Buxton, Brad, Blue Cross Blue Shield. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., August 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Canary, Patrick. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Healthcare" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., July 9, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Carpenter, Valerie, ed. (2002) "Expanding Health Insurance: The AMA Proposal for Reform," American Medical Association, November, Chicago, Ill.

Carter, John. (1984) "Concentration Change and the Structure Performance Debate: An Interpretive Essay," Managerial and Decision Economics 5:4 (December):204-12.

Center for Law and Social Policy and Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. (2001) State Policy Documentation Project.

Chao, Elaine. "Report on Association Health Plans: Improving Access to Affordable Quality Health Care for Small Businesses." News Release, U.S. Department of Labor, September 13, 2002. Available at http://www.dol.gov/opa/media/press/pwba/PWBA2002535.htm. Accessed January 2003.

Chao, Elaine. Testimony on "The Small Business Health Care Crisis: Possible Solutions" before the Committee on Small Business and Entrepreneurship, U.S. Senate, February 5, 2003, Washington, D.C.

Chollet, Deborah and Adele Kirk. (1998) Understanding Individual Health Insurance Markets. Kaiser Family Foundation, March, Menlo Park, Calif.

Citro, Constance F. and Robert T. Michael, eds. (1995) Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

Close, Brad. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., August 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Coate, Malcolm and James Langenfeld. (1993) "Entry under the Merger Guidelines 1982-1992," Antitrust Bulletin 38:3, pages 557-92.

CONSAD Research Corporation. (1998) The Projected Impacts of the Expanded Portability and Health Insurance Coverage Act on Health Insurance Coverage. CONSAD Research Corporation, Pittsburgh, Penn.

"Conseco Bails Out of Major Medical," Indianapolis Star, February 17, 2002.

Conway, Gerard. (2001) "Competition in the Managed Care Health Insurance Market in New York State: A Regional Analysis," Medical Society of the State of New York.

Cooper, Mark. Testimony on "Are All Online Travel Sites Good for the Consumer: An Examination of Supplier-Owned Online Travel Sites," before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., July 18, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Cooper, Mark. Testimony on "Electricity Markets: California," before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., March 20 and 22, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Cooper, Mark. Testimony on "The Airline Mergers and Their Effects on American Consumers," before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., March 21, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Davis, Sammy. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Healthcare" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., July 9, 2001, Washington, D.C.

DeFrancesco, LeAnne et al. (2002) "State of the States," State Coverage Initiatives. Academy for Health Services Research and Health Policy, January, Washington, D.C.

De Posada, Robert, The Latino Coalition. Testimony on "The Small Business Health Market: Bad Reforms, Higher Prices, and Fewer Choices" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., July 11, 2002, Washington, D.C.

De Posada, Robert, The Latino Coalition. Testimony on "The Uninsured and Affordable Health Care Coverage" before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-98. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 28, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Dingell, John. Testimony on "The Uninsured and Affordable Health Care Coverage" before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-98. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 28, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Dranove, David, Mark Shanley, and William White. (1993) "Price and Concentration in Hospital Markets: The Switch from Patient-Driven to Payee-Driven Competition," Journal of Law and Economics 36:1 Part 1 (April):179-204.

Dressler, Donald, Insurance Services for Western Growers Association. Testimony on "The Health Organization for Bona Fide Trade and Professional Associations" before the Committee on Education and the Workforce, U.S. House of Representatives, March 25, 1999, Washington, D.C.

Duchon, Lisa et al. (2001) Security Matters: How Instability in Health Insurance Puts U.S. Workers at Risk. Commonwealth Fund, December, New York, N.Y.

Fialka, John. (1997) War by Other Means: Economic Espionage in America. New York: W. W. Norton.

Fiscella, K. P. et al. (2000) "Inequality in Health: Addressing Socioeconomic, Racial and Ethnic Disparities in Health Care," Journal of the American Medical Association 283:19 (May 17):2579-82.

Fletcher, Hon. Dr. Ernie. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care," before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., Feb. 6, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Fox, Claude. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 22, 2001.

Freeman, Dennis. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 22, 2001.

Fronstin, Paul. (2001) "Sources of Health Insurance and Characteristics of the Uninsured: Analysis of the March 2001 Current Population Survey," Employee Benefits Research Institute, December, Washington, D.C.

Gabel, Jon. (2000) "Job-Based Health Insurance in 2000: Premiums Rise Sharply While Coverage Grows," Health Affairs 19:5 (Sep/Oct):144-51.

Gabel, Jon et al. (1999) "Health Benefits of Small Employers in 1998," Kaiser Family Foundation and Health Research and Educational Trust, Menlo Park, Calif.

Garber, Alan. (2001) "Evidence-Based Coverage Policy," Health Affairs 20:5 (Sep/Oct):62-82.

Gilligan, Thomas. (2002) "Industrial Concentration," The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Available at http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/IndustrialConcentration.html.

Goodman, John C. and Gerald L. Musgrave. (1988) "Freedom of Choice in Health Insurance," NCPA Study No. 134, National Center for Policy Analysis, Dallas, Texas.

Goodman, John C. (1980) Regulation of Medical Care: Is the Price Too High? San Francisco, Calif: Cato Institute.

Goodman, John and Merrill Mathews. (1997) "The Cost of Health Insurance Mandates," Brief Analysis No. 237, National Center for Policy Analysis, August 13, Dallas, Texas.

Graham, John. OIRA, Office of Management and Budget. Testimony on "Reducing Regulatory and Paperwork Burdens on Small Healthcare Providers: Proposals from the Executive Branch" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., July 25, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Graham, John, OIRA, Office of Management and Budget. Testimony on "The Cost of Regulation to Small Business" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., June 6, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Grob, George. Testimony on "Reducing Regulatory and Paperwork Burdens on Small Healthcare Providers: Proposals from the Executive Branch" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., July 25, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Gupta, Barnali, Amoz Kats, and Debashis Pal. (1994) "Upstream Monopoly, Downstream Competition, and Spatial Price Discrimination," Regional Science and Urban Economics 24:5 (October):341-57.

Hahn, Robert. Testimony on "The Cost of Regulation to Small Business" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., June 6, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Hausman, J., G. Leonard, and J. D. Zona. (1992) "A Proposed Method for Analyzing Competition among Differentiated Products," Antitrust Law Journal 60:889-900.

Hendershott, Velma. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 22, 2001.

Health Insurance Association of America. (1999) Antitrust Waivers for Physicians: Costs and Consequences, HIAA, June, Washington, D.C.

Hirschey, Mark and James Pappas. (2000) Fundamentals of Managerial Economics 6th ed. Chicago: Dryden Press.

Holahan, John. (2001) "Health Status and the Costs of Expanding Insurance Coverage," Health Affairs 20:6 (Nov/Dec):279-86.

Hortado, M. and J. Corrigan, eds. (2001) Envisioning the National Health Care Quality Report, Institute of Medicine. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.

Horsky, Dan and Paul Nelson. (1992) "New Brand Positioning and Pricing in an Oligopolistic Market," Marketing Science 11:2 (Spring):133-53.

Hughes, Robert. (2002) "Affordability in Health Care Survey – Trends in American Micro-Business," National Association for the Self-Employed, June, Washington, D.C.

Institute of Medicine. (1993) Access to Health Care in America. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.

Institute of Medicine. (2001) Coverage Matters: Insurance and Health Care. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.

"Insurance Watch – Conseco: Company Phases Out Half of Health Insurance Unit," American Health Line, August 10, 2001.

Internal Revenue Service. (2002) "Part IV. Items of General Interest, Archer MSAs," Announcement 2002-90, Internal Revenue Service, Washington, D.C.

Jencks, S. et al. (2000) "Quality of Medical Care Delivered to Medicare Beneficiaries: A Profile at State and National Levels." Journal of the American Medical Association 284:13 (October 4):1670-76.

Jensen, Amy. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-51. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., April 4, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Jensen, Gail, Kevin Cotter, and Michael Morrisey. (1995) "State Insurance Regulation and the Employer's Decision to Self-Insure." Journal of Risk and Insurance 62:2 (June):185-213.

Jensen, Gail A. and Michael Morrisey, "Mandated Benefit Laws and Employer-Sponsored Health Insurance," Health Insurance Association of America, January 25, 1999, Washington, D.C.

Joensen, Mark. Testimony on "Association Health Plans – Promoting Health Care Accessibility" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 106 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 16, 2000, Washington, D.C.

Kaiser Family Foundation/Health Research and Educational Trust. (2002) Employer Health Benefits: 2002 Annual Survey. Menlo Park, Calif.

Katz, Michael and Harvey Rosen. (1991) Microeconomics. Boston: Irwin McGraw-Hill.

Keating, Raymond. Testimony on "The Small Business Health Market: Bad Reforms, Higher Prices, and Fewer Choices" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., July 11, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Kellerman, Arthur. Committee on the Study of the Consequences of Uninsurance. Testimony on "The Uninsured and Affordable Health Care Coverage" before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-98. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 28, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Koehler, Ken. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., August 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Kuhn, Michelle. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Healthcare" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., July 9, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Lane, Sylvia and Anastasios Papathanasis. (1983) "Certification and Industry Concentration Ratios," Antitrust Bulletin 28:2 (Summer):381-95.

Langer, Andrew, National Federation of Independent Business. Testimony on "The Cost of Regulation to Small Business" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., June 6, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Laudicina, Susan S., Betsy Losleben, and Natasha Walker. (2001) "State Legislative Health Care and Insurance Issues, Survey of Plans 2001." Office of Policy and Representation, Blue Cross Blue Shield Association, December, Washington, D.C.

Layzer, Jean I. and Ann Collins. (2001) Access to Child Care for Low-Income Working Families Report. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Washington, D.C.

Lehnhard, Mary Nell. Testimony on "Association Health Plans – Promoting Health Care Accessability" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 106 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 16, 2000, Washington, D.C.

Lehnhard, Mary Nell. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-41. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 6, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Levin, Ryan. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-51. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., April 4, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Levitt, Larry et al., Kaiser Family Foundation, and Gabel, Jon et al., Health Research and Educational Trust. (2002) Employer Health Benefits: 2002 Annual Survey. Kaiser Family Foundation and Health Research and Educational Trust, Menlo Park, Calif.

Levitt, Larry et al., Kaiser Family Foundation, and Gabel, Jon et al., Health Research and Educational Trust. (2000) Employer Health Benefits: 2000 Annual Survey. Kaiser Family Foundation and Health Research and Educational Trust, Menlo Park, Calif.

Litow, Mark, Millman USA. Testimony on "The Small Business Health Market: Bad Reforms, Higher Prices, and Fewer Choices" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., July 11, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Lohr, K. and A. Walker, eds. (1990) Medicare: A Strategy for Quality Assurance. Institute of Medicine. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.

Long, Stephen. (2001) "Have Small-Group Health Insurance Purchasing Alliances Increased Coverage?" Health Affairs 20:1 (Jan/Feb):154-63.

Manzullo, Donald. Testimony of committee chair on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., August 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Matthews, Merrill. (2002) "The Benefits of Association Group Health Insurance." Council for Affordable Health Insurance, Issues and Answers No. 114, February, Washington, D.C.

Matthews, Merrill and Raymond Keating. Testimony on "The Small Business Health Market: Bad Reforms, Higher Prices, and Fewer Choices" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., July 11, 2002, Washington, D.C.

McCarty, Mick, Blue Cross Blue Shield. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-51. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., April 4, 2002, Washington, D.C.

McClellan, Mark, Council of Economic Advisers. Testimony before the Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions Committee on the Uninsured, U.S. Senate, March 12, 2002.

McGuigan, James, Charles Moyer, and Frederick Harris. (1999) Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategy, and Tactics 8th ed. Mason, Ohio: Thompson South-Western.

McIntosh, David. Testimony on "The Cost of Regulation to Small Business" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., June 6, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Milam, James. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., August 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Miller & Chevalier Employee Benefits Practice Group. (2002) "Top Twenty HIPAA Privacy Questions Asked by Employers with Group Health Plans," ERISA and Benefits Alert 4:10, October, Washington, D.C. Accessed March 10, 2003.

Mills, Robert. (2002) "Health Insurance Coverage: 2001," Current Population Reports, P60-220, U.S. Census Bureau, September, Washington, D. C.

Mishel, Lawrence, Jared Bernstein, and Tiffany Thacher. (2002) It Ain't Over Til It's Really Over: Slow Growth Will Lead to Rising Unemployment in 2002 and High Unemployment in 2003. Economic Policy Institute, Washington, D.C.

Moser, Robert. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 22, 2001.

Mulkey, Marian. (2001) "Small Businesses, Information, and the Decision to Offer Health Insurance," Health Affairs 20:5 (Sep/Oct):278-82.

Nelson, Wayne. Testimony on "The Small Business Health Market: Bad Reforms, Higher Prices, and Fewer Choices" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., July 11, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Nelson, Charles and Robert Mills. (2002) "The Characteristics of People Reporting State Children's Health Insurance Program Coverage in the March 2001 Current Population Survey," U.S. Census Bureau, August, Washington, D.C.

O'Brien, John. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 22, 2001.

O'Sullivan, Arthur and Steven Sheffrin. (2001) Economics: Principles and Tools 2nd ed. Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Prentice Hall.

Patel, Vip. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 12, 2002.

Peterson, Chris L. and Christine Devere. "Health Insurance: Federal Data Sources for Analyses of the Uninsured," CRS Report for Congress, Congressional Research Service, February 7, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Pollack, Ronald. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 12, 2002.

Pollitz, Karen. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 12, 2002.

Pollitz, Karen, Richard Sorian, and Kathy Thomas. (2001) How Accessible Is Individual Health Insurance for Consumers in Less-Than-Perfect Health? Kaiser Family Foundation, June, Menlo Park, Calif.

Primus, Wendell and Ed Lazere. (2001) TANF Supplemental Grants Should Be Extended for Fiscal Year 2002. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, Washington, D.C.

Reljic, Boro. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-51. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., April 4, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Rosenthal, Meredith. (2001) "Managed Care and Market Power: Physician Organizations in Four Markets," Health Affairs 20:5 (Sep/Oct):187-93.

Rowland, Diane, Kaiser Family Foundation. Testimony on "The Uninsured and Affordable Health Care Coverage" before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-98. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 28, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Sacher, Seth and Louis Silvia. (1998) "Antitrust Issues in Defining the Product Market for Hospital Services," International Journal of the Economics of Business 5:2, 181-202.

Salinger, Michael. (1990) "The Concentration Margins Relationship Reconsidered," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Brooking Institution, pages 287-321.

Scheffman, David and Pablo Spiller. (1992) "Buyers' Strategies, Entry Barriers, and Competition," Economic Inquiry 30:3 (July), 418-36.

Scherer, F. M. and D. Ross. (1990) Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance 3rd ed. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.

Schone, Barbara. (2001) "Assessing the Impact of Health Plan Choice," Health Affairs 20:1 (Jan/Feb):267-75.

Schriver, Melinda L. and Grace-Marie Arnett. (1998) "Uninsured Rates Rise Dramatically in States with Strictest Health Insurance Regulations," Backgrounder No. 1211, Heritage Foundation, August 14, Washington, D.C.

Scully, Thomas. Testimony on "Reducing Regulatory and Paperwork Burdens on Small Healthcare Providers: Proposals from the Executive Branch" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives , 107 Cong. 1st Sess., July 25, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Shaker, Steven and Mark Gembicki. (1999) The War Room Guide to Competitive Intelligence. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Shalek, Scott. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., August 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Simantov, Elisabeth. (2001) "Market Failure? Individual Insurance Markets for Older Americans," Health Affairs 20:4 (Jul/Aug):139-49.

Smedley, B., A. Stith, and A. Nelson, eds. (2002) Unequal Treatment: Confronting Racial and Ethnic Disparities in Health Care. Institute of Medicine. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.

Talent, James. Testimony on "Association Health Plans – Promoting Health Care Accessibility" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 106 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 16, 2000, Washington, D.C.

Taylor, Humphrey. (2002) "How and Why the Health Insurance System Will Collapse," Health Affairs 21:6 (Nov/Dec):195-200.

Terhune, Chad. "Association Health Carriers Face Stricter Rules by Insurance Panel," Wall Street Journal, December 12, 2002.

Terhune, Chad. "Some Fear Hidden Risks as Health-Insurance Pools Gain Momentum," Wall Street Journal, Eastern ed., August 26, 2002.

Thorpe, Kenneth. (1999) "Why Are Workers Uninsured? Employer-Sponsored Health Insurance in 1997," Health Affairs 18:2 (Mar/Apr):213-18.

Tucker, Irvin. (2003) Economics for Today. Mason, Ohio: Thompson South-Western.

Turner, Grace Marie, Galen Institute. Testimony on "The Uninsured and Affordable Health Care Coverage" before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-98. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 28, 2002, Washington, D.C.

U.S. Census Bureau. (2000) "Concentration of Firms," Health Care & Social Assistance – Subject Series, 1997 Economic Census, October 25, Washington, D.C.

U.S. Census Bureau. (2002) "Health Insurance Coverage: 2001," Subject Series P60-220, Washington, D.C.

U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. (1999) National Study of Child Care for Low-Income Families. Washington, D.C.

U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission. "1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines with April 8, 1997 Revisions to Section 4 on Efficiencies," Washington, D.C. Available at http://www.ftc.gov/bc/docs/horizmer.htm. Accessed December 9, 2002.

U.S. House of Representatives. Hearing before the Committee on Small Business. "Can Improved Compliance with the Regulatory Flexibility Act Resuscitate Small Health Care Providers?" 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., April 10, 2002, Washington, D.C.

U.S. House of Representatives. Hearing before the Committee on Education and the Workforce. "Enhancing Retirement Security: H.R. 10, The Comprehensive Retirement Security and Pension Reform Act of 2001," 107 Cong, 1st Sess., April 5, 2001, Washington, D.C.

U.S. House of Representatives. Hearing before the Committee on Small Business. "Small Business Access to Health Care." Serial No. 107-41. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 6, 2002, Washington, D.C.

U.S. House of Representatives. Hearing before the Committee on Small Business. "Small Business Access to Health Care." Serial No. 107-51. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., April 4, 2002, Washington, D.C.

U.S. Small Business Administration. "Study of the Administrative Costs and Actuarial Values of Small Health Plans." Office of Advocacy, January 2003, Washington, D.C.

Weber, Douglas. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 1st Sess., July 9, 2001, Washington, D.C.

Weil, Alan, Urban Institute. Testimony on "The Uninsured and Affordable Health Care Coverage" before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-98. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 28, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Weil, Alan. Testimony before the Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions, U.S. Senate, March 12, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Wenger, Jeffrey B. (2001) Divided We Fall: Deserving Workers Slip through America's Patchwork Unemployment Insurance System. Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute.

Werden, Gregory. (1998) "Demand Elasticities in Antitrust Analysis," Antitrust Law Journal, 66:363-414.

Westerfield, Donald. (1991) Mandated Health Care: Issues And Strategies. New York: Praeger.

Westerfield, Donald. (1991) National Health Care: Law, Policy, Strategy. New York: Praeger.

Westerfield, Donald and Paul Wilson (1989) "COBRA Strikes Business in the Jugular," Management Accounting (January):36?38.

Westerfield, Donald. (1994) "Federal Health Care Mandates: Small Business at Risk," Proceedings of the Business and Health Administration Association Annual Meeting, Chicago, March 16-18, pages 119-23.

Whitfield, Ed. Testimony on "The Uninsured and Affordable Health Care Coverage" before the Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives. Serial No. 107-98. 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 28, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Wilson, Isabella. Testimony on "Small Business Access to Health Care" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 107 Cong. 2nd Sess., August 14, 2002, Washington, D.C.

Wilson, Paul and Donald Westerfield. (1994) "Small Group Health Reform and Association Plan 'Poison Pills,'" Proceedings of the Business and Health Administration Association Annual Meeting, Chicago, March 16-18, pages 124-28.

Wilson, Paul. Testimony on "Association Health Plans – Promoting Health Care Accessability" before the Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, 106 Cong. 2nd Sess., February 16, 2000, Washington, D.C.

Wirl, F. (1991) "Dynamic Demand and Noncompetitive Pricing Strategies," Journal of Economics 54:3, pages 105-21.

[page]

Dr. Donald L. Westerfield is a Professor in the Graduate School of Webster University and is a Senior Fellow with the National Center for Policy Analysis. He received his B.B.A and M.A. degrees from the University of Miami, Fla., and his Ph.D. from Saint Louis University. Dr. Westerfield is the author of four books: War Powers: The President, The Congress, and the Question of War (New York: Praeger Publishers, 1996), foreword by Hon. Donald H. Rumsfeld; National Health Care: Law, Policy, Strategy (New York: Praeger Publishers, 1993); Donald L. Westerfield and Hon. Thomas Curtis, Congressional Intent (New York: Praeger Publishers, 1992), foreword by Hon. Donald H. Rumsfeld; and Mandated Health Care: Issues And Strategies (New York: Praeger Publishers, 1991), foreword by Hon. Thomas Curtis.

Dr. Westerfield's academic works include over 125 scholarly and professional papers and presentations. He is a referee/reviewer for two scholarly journals and is listed in Marquis Who's Who in the World and in Marquis Who's Who in the Midwest. He was a Director of Webster University's London, England, campus and has taught in the Vrie Universiteit in Amsterdam, The Netherlands, and in Shanghai University of Finance and Economics in Shanghai, People's Republic of China. He has also taught in Webster University's other foreign campuses in Vienna, Austria; Geneva, Switzerland; Leiden, The Netherlands; and Eindhoven, The Netherlands.

In addition to his scholarly interests, Dr. Westerfield is a single- and multi-engine instrument-rated commercial pilot and flight instructor and works with the deaf community in American Sign Language.

Dr. Westerfield is also CEO and Owner of Economic Consultants in Saint Louis, Missouri. His consulting interests include econometrics, statistics, business strategy, economics of health care, intelligence, counterintelligence and industrial security.