Private School Choice: Options for Texas Children

Executive Summary

The fundamental problem with Texas public schools, and nationwide, is that not enough children are engaged in useful learning. Numerous surveys have found that 40 percent to 60 percent of suburban, urban and rural students are not engaged with public school content. Individual students require different kinds of schools and curricula because of their particular learning styles, interests and abilities. The public school system, however, has created schools that strive for uniformity and comprehensiveness — grouping students by age, rather than by specific subject interest and ability.

Increasing the number and variety of schools competing for students and teachers would give public schools an incentive to improve. Specialized schools that compete for students would help teachers and students find curricula that best meet their needs, and both public and private schools would have incentives to become more efficient. Widespread improvement requires opportunities for families to choose from different instructional approaches that harness educators’ talents and passions to address the differences in school-age children.

School choice for Texas children could be implemented through universal tuition vouchers, as well as corporate and individual tuition tax credits. However, the most important reforms would give Texas students the option to choose to attend private schools. A voucher program open to all Texas K-12 students — enrolled in public or private schools — could be structured in a way that does not reduce the current funding per public school student, and adds no new cost to taxpayers. Indeed, the program would increase the funding available per public school student and there would be substantial long-term savings to public schools in reduced capital costs.

Consider:

If public school students had a voucher worth 75 percent of average spending in 2013-2014 ($6,667), about 450,000 students would use them, saving taxpayers $1.87 billion over two years.

If, in addition, current private school students had a voucher phased in over three years and 60 percent used the voucher, net total savings to taxpayers after two years would be about $580 million.

Additionally, over 10 years, reduced debt service and capital outlays could save local school districts roughly $24,000 per voucher, or $10.8 billion.

There are no legal barriers to a school choice voucher system. The U.S. Supreme Court ruled that vouchers are constitutional if parents choose the schools and the program favors no particular religion. At the state level, in 1995 the Texas Supreme Court held that the state legislature could establish a system of school choice.

A feasible voucher program could significantly lower discipline issues and dropout rates, allow for greater school choice and competition, and would not reduce the funding per public school student. Additional benefits of school choice include higher teacher pay due to the increased demand for high-quality teachers, increased private spending on schooling, and higher public school performance and standards due to increased competition for students and specialization of schools.

Introduction1

The fundamental problem with Texas public schools, as with public education generally in the United States, is that children are not engaged in useful learning. Far too many children are confused, overwhelmed or bored. As a result, they learn little, become discipline problems, and drop out at high rates. The worst problems are in the urban schools attended by the poor, but they cannot be solely attributed to low income or an urban environment. Poor performance and falling productivity are system-wide issues.2  In scattered exceptions, one or more individual leaders succeed against incredible odds, but they are typically unable to sustain, spread and replicate high performing schools or school systems.3

Widespread improvement requires opportunities for families to choose from different instructional approaches that harness educators’ talents and passions to address the differences in school-age children. But this can only be accomplished when families are provided a diverse menu of public and private schooling options, including for-profit schools, independent schools and parochial schools.

School choice for Texas children could be implemented through universal tuition vouchers, as well as corporate and individual tuition tax credits. As part of a more encompassing transformation, the first steps within public school systems might include open enrollment, additional magnet schools and widespread charters. However, the most important reforms would give Texas students the option to choose to attend private schools.  

Texas Public Schools

Currently, about 4.9 million children are enrolled in the Texas public school system. Enrollment is increasing at a rate of about 2 percent per year, mainly due to population increases. The average per-pupil maintenance and operating (M&O) expenditure is about $8,714 per student, an increase of 12 percent since 2005.4  For comparison, the national average annual per-pupil spending is $10,770, according to the National Education Association.5  In Texas, general instruction expenditures average about $5,150 per student, whereas spending on instruction for special education students averages about $8,700 per student.6  The reported dropout rate for Texas public schools was 14.1 percent during the 2006-2007 school year; by the 2011-2012 school year, that rate had declined to 8.4 percent.7

In 2011, 86 percent of students tested met the standard for mathematics on the Texas Assessment of Knowledge and Skill (TAKS).8  However, for comparison with other states, the National Assessment of Education Performance (NAEP) is a good measure. The NAEP is the nation’s largest continuing test of academic performance, and its tests are uniform nationwide.9  On the NAEP test, in 2011, less than half (49 percent) of Texas public school 8th grade students scored as proficient or advanced in mathematics, only one-third (34 percent) were proficient or advanced in science, and less than one-third (29 percent) scored proficient or advanced in reading.10  Notably however, Texas students received better scores in mathematics than other states with roughly similar per-pupil expenditures.11

Student Disengagement in Texas Public Schools

Students are engaged in the learning process when they “take pride not simply in earning the formal indicators of success (grades), but in understanding the material and incorporating or internalizing it in their lives.”12 A key to engagement in school is being motivated to learn.13  The importance of engagement to student outcomes has been extensively documented.14  Keeping students interested helps them learn material more quickly, allows them to retain information longer, keeps them out of trouble and reduces dropout rates.15  Unfortunately, many public school students are not engaged in their schoolwork. Indeed, numerous surveys have found that 40 percent to 60 percent of suburban, urban and rural students are not engaged with the material they are being taught in school.16

Obstacles to engagement include lack of specialized schools and curricula, and a lack of incentives for schools to innovate.

The Diversity of Students versus the One-Size-Fits-All Approach of Public Schools. Individual students require different kinds of schools and curricula because of their particular learning styles, interests and abilities. Public education, however, has created schools that strive for uniformity and comprehensiveness — teaching the same things, in the same way, to all students.

One Teacher Can’t Meet the Needs of All Students in a Typical Classroom. Public school classrooms usually contain students with a wide spectrum of subject interests and diversity of learning styles. Even students from families with similar incomes and ethnic backgrounds have very different goals, subject interests17 and learning styles.18  No single curriculum or teacher can accommodate all the students in a typical classroom.

Because public schools do not tailor their services to meet the unique needs of their students, they often adopt ineffective, shallow, one-size-fits-all teaching methods        and curricula.

School Uniformity and Size. Large, comprehensive “shopping mall high schools” are an attempt to address the challenges of student diversity.19  Whereas student engagement in learning requires creating a sense of community, distinct purpose and identity,20 megaschools lack a coherent mission.21 Furthermore, they are hard to manage,22 and are vulnerable to fraud with respect to accountability tests and measures.23

Public Schools Group Students by Address. Public school attendance zones assign children to schools according to home address. Thus, attendance zones force each school to address every major educational preference its official neighborhood might contain, or at least appear to do so, in effect mandating an unspecialized school in every neighborhood.24  

 Furthermore, because most students live in areas where families have similar income levels, and students attend schools based upon where they live, the U.S. public school system is highly segregated by socioeconomic status, and therefore by race and ethnicity. Today, about 67 percent of African Americans and 75 percent of Hispanics attend public schools with roughly 90 percent of the same ethnic group.25

Public Schools Group Students by Age. Students typically have natural tendencies to perform better on certain subjects than others. Thus, grouping students by age, rather than specific subject interest and ability, reduces student engagement and academic achievement.26 It is another reason that students at higher achievement levels are prone to lose interest,27 while students at lower achievement levels may feel overwhelmed.28  It is well known that age is not a key determinant of the proper level and pace of instruction.29

Large disparities in student intellect within individual classrooms cause many teachers to lower their standards so that the majority of their students can “succeed,” but then many underachieve (or worse, disrupt and eventually drop out) because of boredom.30 The effects of classroom composition are magnified after the 5th grade, when students rather than teachers set the pace for their academic achievement.31

Furthermore, due to the diverse needs of students, teachers often have difficulty motivating and communicating with individual students.32 Teachers and school officials often come into conflict with parents and each other, especially in large urban district schools where students are especially diverse.33

Harvard University education researcher Paul E. Peterson has written, “The general consensus is that it doesn’t work having all these kids together. For classroom teachers, the challenges can be enormous.”34  There are no “best practices” for highly diverse groups of students. “Watering down” practices appear to be especially debilitating in inner-city schools,35 where most students perform below grade level on essential subjects.36  

Lack of Incentives to Innovate. In school districts across the country, regulation and control by state and local officials have drastically limited the autonomy of teachers in preparing their own lessons. In many cases, teachers must follow a timetable and strict guidelines on what, when and, in some cases, how they should teach their students.37  Such drastic measures allow for little discretion to adapt unique teaching abilities to their particular mix of students. As a result, students are forced to learn material in ways that are not conductive to their teachers’ talents or the personal learning characteristics of the               students themselves.

Incentives of Public School Teachers. Furthermore, neither a teacher’s years of experience nor her level of education have been found to be strong indicators of student performance, yet there are no other factors that impact public school teachers’ base salary.38  Uniform pay schedules are less likely to create an overall shortage of teachers and more likely to reduce incentives, quality and equity.39 

Public school systems provide few monetary incentives for outstanding teachers to remain in the classroom; their pay is usually identical to less effective teachers, which undermines efforts to attract and retain high quality teachers.40  Consider:

Scores on the ACT (formerly known as the American College Test), an exam used to assess student readiness for college, are a good determinate of future teacher success, but teachers with higher ACT scores have higher turnover rates than teachers with lower than average ACT scores.41 

Furthermore, only low ability teachers feel they could achieve successful career progression with a single salary schedule.42   

In addition, because improved performance does not lead to a higher salary or benefits, a uniform pay schedule provides no monetary incentive for mediocre teachers to improve.43 

Another result of uniform salary schedules, of particular relevance to student disengagement, is that there are often large shortages of qualified teachers in key fields such as math and science.44 In these specialties, private-sector companies offer quite lucrative salaries. Indeed:

Only 61 percent of math and 71 percent of science teachers, nationally, majored in their field of teaching.45 

About 31 percent of all secondary schools had serious problems hiring mathematics, life sciences or physical   sciences teachers.46 

More experienced teachers are much more likely to be found in suburban school districts, where base salary rates are higher and job stress is lower. Inner-city schools that have the most urgent need for engaging teachers have higher than average teacher turnover rates, resulting in less experienced teachers for students most in need of quality teachers.47  

The Lack of Accountability in Public Schools. There are two main sources of accountability in K-12 education: government officials and families.48  Since public schools do not receive funding directly from their customers, consumer accountability is minimal. Without parental scrutiny, schools have little incentive to remove ineffective educators, improve services or reduce costs.

Government demands for improvement and the ultimate threat of closure have failed to produce the type of continuous improvement necessary to turn around failing schools.49  Under the current system, even schools deemed successful often become complacent and end difficult efforts to make further improvements.50 Accountability to parents and students, in contrast, can produce continuous improvement in all aspects of school services.51

The 2002 federal No Child Left Behind (NCLB) law and much new state legislation implore schools to meet certain standards — that is, have a certain percentage of students achieve proficiency or above on state assessments, achieve high graduation and attendance rates and so forth. However, school system personnel face few if any major repercussions when they fail to meet their objectives. Thus, low performing schools continue to operate year  after year.52 

The public school focus on specific standards set by national, state and local governments has led to an emphasis on the specifics of the official accountability measures. The resulting practice of “teaching to tests” that are the basis of school assessments has greatly narrowed curricula to tested items and to lessons aimed at standardized test preparation.53 For example, there is greater emphasis on math and reading test questions, and much less coverage of untested subjects like history and social studies.54

The Role of Competition and Prices in Education55

Increasing the number and variety of schools competing for students and teachers would give public schools an incentive to improve. Specialized schools that compete for students would help teachers and students find curricula that best meet their needs, and both public and private schools would have incentives to become more efficient. Indeed, different schools serve different students best. For example, an NCPA analysis of standardized test scores for a number of Dallas-area public schools found that some schools had better results teaching some groups of students but not others.56  Furthermore, parents look for various characteristics, aside from cost, that are important in their child’s education. Some parents, for instance, value a school with a structured curriculum and strict discipline; others may prefer a looser approach to learning.

Like health care, however, education also needs price competition — without price competition, there is no quality competition. The classic symptoms of price control — misallocation of resources and declining quality — are abundant in K-12 education. Traditional and chartered public schools are forbidden, by law, to charge tuition, and many voucher programs operate like the one in Milwaukee, where schools that enroll voucher users must accept the voucher as full payment.57 All of the prominent federal- and state-level school system reform efforts have implicitly assumed that price control is acceptable for the education industry. But the disappointing outcomes of school system reform efforts so far say otherwise. The gains in educational achievement of students enrolled in choice programs have been modest. Milton Friedman termed these “charity vouchers.”58  The education voucher program proposed below is        much broader. 

The amount of the publicly funded voucher need not equal the cost of education in every private school. Ideally, it should be adequate to pay tuition at a school that charges the average or median amount. Private school tuition at parochial schools, for example, tends to be lower than the average private school.

It is important that education consumers and their parents have incentives to shop for schools based on price and other qualities. These incentives include paying part of the cost from their own funds and/or contributing their own time and skills to the school. By contrast, free schooling eliminates the incentive of parents to shop for schools that are efficient. Additional tuition levies have the most impact on low-income families. But third parties can address the affordability/access issues. Tuition levies can be publicly or privately financed on a case-by-case basis or according to academic talent (scholarship) or financial need. Mandating free-only schooling options would eliminate school choices that low-income families have found the money to buy and that often could not exist otherwise. Moreover, mandating free, subsidized schooling short-circuits the product development process that transforms initially costly services into widely affordable options.

Effect of Vouchers on Private School Enrollment. What effect would voucher programs have on private school enrollment?  This can be estimated based on calculations made for a proposed “Texas Taxpayer Savings Grants” program.

An estimated 235,241 students attended private schools in Texas during the 2007-2008 school year.59  Assuming vouchers equal to 60 percent of Texas’ average per-pupil maintenance and operations expenditure in 2011 were available to all current public school students and incoming kindergarten students (but not to private school students),  it was estimated:60 

Some 314,245 to 383,501 public school students would transfer to private schools [see the side bar “Texas Taxpayer Savings   Grants Program”].

As a result, private total enrollment in private schools would rise to about 583,000.

With per pupil expenditure in Texas schools for maintenance and operations averaging about $8,801 per student, a 60 percent voucher would be nearly $5,281 per year, and public schools would gain more than $3,520 for each student who transferred to a private school.

Public schools spend more for special education students. Though the majority of private schools, including Catholic ones, accept about 90 percent of the students who apply, a greater number of available vouchers would assure more choices for special education students.61 

Furthermore, each time a private school student transfers to a public school costs to taxpayers increase. According to the National Catholic Educational Association, nationwide Catholic school enrollment declined 20 percent — by more than one-half million students — from 2000 to 2010.62  As Catholic schools have closed and consolidated, the transfer of these students to public schools has raised public school costs by billions of dollars. Thus, reversing the decline in parochial school enrollment would save public schools the additional expense of educating transferring students.63

Depending on the voucher program available, more or fewer students would be attracted to private schools. However, parochial and independent schools would have to raise their own funds for capital expenditures. Furthermore, the program would likely be phased in over a number of years, allowing private school enrollment to gradually increase. Thus, a voucher program could be structured so that public schools do not experience a net decrease in funding.

A Feasible Education Voucher Program for Texas K-12 Students

A voucher program open to all Texas K-12 students — enrolled in public or private schools — could be structured in a way that does not reduce current funding per public school student and adds no new cost to taxpayers.

In 2011, John Merrifield and Joseph L. Bast estimated the impact of providing vouchers to Texas public school students worth 60 percent of the average maintenance and operations expenditure.68 This analysis applies a similar methodology to updated data and varies the amount of the voucher.69   

Impact on Enrollment. Barry R. Chiswick and Stella Koutroumanes (C&K) calculated that a $1 reduction in private school tuition in 1990 increased the probability of choosing a private school by 0.0021 percent.70 After adjusting for inflation, the marginal impact of a $1 voucher in 2011 is 0.00122 percent. For example, a hypothetical $4,500 voucher would increase the enrollment rate by five-and-one-half percent (0.0549 = $4,500 x 0.0000122).

Voucher programs implemented in San Antonio, Texas and Milwaukee, Wisconsin, had participation rates differing from those predicted by the C&K coefficient. By the second year of those programs, 6.8 percent of San Antonio’s Edgewood ISD public school population and 7.26 percent of Milwaukee public school students had received a voucher. The savings associated with these participation rates could be higher than the calculations in this study.

Applying the C&K coefficient calculation to various levels of vouchers yields a range of private school enrollment rate increases. [See Table I.] 

 This analysis assumes that if legislation authorizing vouchers were passed in the 2013 regular session of the Texas State Legislature, it would be effective for the 2013-2014 school year. The total population of K-12 students in Texas during the 2013-2014 school year is expected to be 5,526,782 (5,203,927 in public schools and 322,855 in private schools). Thus, with a $4,500 voucher, 303,625 (.0549 x 5,526,782) students would be expected to shift from public to private schools. Again, various voucher amounts produce varying expected shifts.71    [See Table II.]

Budgetary Impact. Previous experience with a privately funded voucher program in Edgewood, Texas, demonstrates that not all students will shift in the first year, but  almost all expected participants will accept the vouchers and shift by the second year. Merrifield and Bast estimate that 86.7 percent of enrollment shift will occur in the first year, and 100 percent will occur by the second year. 72 Assuming that every participating student receives a maximum $4,500 voucher, the annual savings per student is $4,389 ($8,889 – $4,500). If vouchers are not made available to current private school students, cumulative savings from all student shifting over the first two years would be about $2.5 billion [see Table III]:

Savings in Year One:                      $1,155,516,935 (303,625 x $4,389 x .0867)

Savings in Year Two:          $1,332,776,164 (303,625 x $4,389)

Combined Two-Year Savings:        $2,488,293,099 ($1,155,516,935 + $1,332,776,164)

Because annual per student savings fall and total participating students rise as voucher amounts increase, maximum savings occur when the voucher amount is half of M&O costs. [See Figure II.]

Vouchers for Current Private School Students. While the Texas Taxpayer Savings Grants program would offer vouchers to current and new kindergarten public school students who switch to private school, current private school students would be ineligible. Instead, the NCPA analysis assumes that current private school students are eligible for a similar tuition grant, phased in over three years.

Assume that the state awards current private school students 33 percent of the voucher given to current public school students in the first year, 66 percent in the second year and 100 percent in the third year. The cumulative award over two years to each private school student would be 50 percent of the cumulative award to a current public school student. [See Table IV.]  This phase-in schedule would eliminate incentives for students to “game the system” by shifting to a public school for a year in order to qualify for the voucher. The voucher could also be phased in by grade.

If a $4,500 voucher is given to current public school students, a voucher worth 33 percent and then 66 percent would be given to the private school student, adding up to $4,500 over two years. If 85 percent of current private school students accept, the two-year cost would be $2,469,621,888 ($4,500 x 322,855 x .85). Table IV shows that costs rise as the voucher amount rises.

When costs of vouchers for current private school students are subtracted from savings generated by shifting students to private schools there is a revenue neutral break-even point. [See Figure III.]  The program will break even when the combined two-year savings  equal the two-year cost of additional vouchers. These break-even points occur around 71 percent, 75 percent, 83 percent and 88 percent of average per pupil state cost. [See Table V.]

Each point maximizes the number of students that receive a voucher without costing more than the  current system.

Voucher Use by Additional Students. The two-year figures in this proposal calculate the cost of a voucher for current private school students while the program is phasing in. Equal vouchers will be awarded to all students in the third year and will increase yearly costs.

There are additional savings not considered in the preceding analysis. Programs providing private school vouchers to public school students have been implemented in Milwaukee, Wisconsin, and the Edgewood School District in San Antonio, Texas; participation in each program grew continuously beyond the first two years. Additional participation in this program by current public school students will increase savings to Texas. These savings could cover the increased costs of a fully                 implemented program.

Projected Costs and Student Enrollment. Texas public school enrollment is projected to be 5.2 million for the 2013-2014 school year. The average cost per public school student for instruction and other maintenance and operating expenses is expected to be $8,889. Additionally, about 322,855 students are forecasted to attend private schools during the 2013-2014 school year. Privately educating those students will save taxpayers over $2.8 billion.73

A voucher worth 75 percent of projected management and operations spending in 2013-2014 equals $6,667 per year. Because the state would otherwise be paying at least $8,889 per public school student, shifting the student with a $6,667 voucher would save $2,222 per student. The voucher system is expected to allow around 450,000 current public school students to switch to private schools, saving a total of $1.87 billion over two years.

A similar, phased-in voucher for current private school students would cost $1.81 billion over two years, if 85 percent of private students accept it. A 60 percent uptake by private students would lower the two-year cost to $1.29 billion. Thus, net savings after two years would be approximately:

$60 million, with a 85 percent uptake by private students; or

$580 million, with a 60 percent uptake by private students.

Savings for Local School Districts and/or Property Taxpayers. Local school property taxes fund most debt service & capital outlays, at a yearly cost per student of $2,313 (2010-2011 school year). Payments on existing debt accounts for 47% of the total, whereas capital outlays are 53 percent of total capital costs, or $1,225 (2010-2011 school year) per student per year. Thus, over 10 years, at the very least, local school districts would save nearly $12,000 per voucher student on capital expenses alone. As existing debt is retired due to the reduction in demand for new classroom space and facilities, there would be additional capital saving. Depending on the debt structure of an individual school district, the savings could double to $24,000 per public school student who switches to a private school.

Vouchers for Special Needs Students. The amount of the voucher should be adjusted to account for the higher costs of special needs students, to be funded from the greater savings to taxpayers when a special needs student switches to a private school.

Texas offers additional funding to schools that provide special education and bilingual or English as a Second Language (ESL) programs. Though the estimates in this study are based on average spending per pupil, under a voucher system this arrangement could be used to prevent “creaming,” where private schools accept only students that require less of a financial investment. Current formulas used by the state adjust a base funding amount by a multiplier for each type of program; the multiplier ranges from 1.1 for ESL students, to 1.7 for nonpublic special education contracts, to 5 for homebound and speech therapy students.74 Classification for special education and bilingual students could be done by a third party or the state. The adjustment for most students would be small, but some students could receive a voucher worth five times the base amount to cover their expenses.

For example, for the 2010-2011 school year:

Spending on basic services and general instruction for regular students averaged about $4,217, whereas all spending on special education students averaged about $11,565.

There were 442,971 students enrolled in special education programs that cost about $5.1 billion per year.

Thus, at 60 percent of maintenance and operating costs, vouchers could be varied from $5,000 to $22,700 after adjusting for special classifications.

Constitutionality of Vouchers. According to an analysis by Allan E. Parker of the Justice Foundation, the U.S. Supreme Court’s Zelman v. Simmons-Harris (2002) decision eliminated the establishment clause of the first amendment of the U.S. Constitution as a possible barrier to school choice programs.75  The Court ruled that the Cleveland, Ohio, voucher program was constitutional because:

It was religiously neutral. The voucher program aided a broad array of recipients, and neither promoted nor restricted voucher use at parochial schools.

 The voucher program did not influence a parent’s selection in any way to choose either religious or nonreligious schools.

The voucher went directly to the parent to use at a school of their choice.

At the state level, in Edgewood IV, the Texas Supreme Court (1995) held that the Legislature could establish a system of school choice.

Using Tax Credits to Fund a Scholarship Program

A tax credit program could be considered as either a supplement or alternative to government financing of private school tuition. The most extensive tax credit program is in Arizona, which implemented Private School Tuition Tax Credits in 1998. State income tax filers can receive a nonrefundable tax credit of up to $500 for an individual filer and $1,000 for joint filers against their state income tax liability for donations to nonprofit school tuition organizations. The state-approved tuition organizations then independently award scholarships to students to attend private schools. School tuition organizations are diverse and vary in size and goals but must give out 90 percent of revenues in scholarship awards. Donors cannot specify who receives their money, but some organizations allow donors to recommend scholarship recipients.

Donations through the Arizona program have expanded significantly, from $2 million in 1998 to $26 million in 2002 and $50 million in 2009. There is no cap on the total amount of donations eligible for the credit. In 2009, 27,657 scholarships were awarded through the various school tuition organizations. The average scholarship is over $1,600 per year, but there is a large variation in the size of the scholarships awarded by tuition groups. Despite other differences, 90 percent of school tuition organizations consider financial need when awarding scholarships. Vicki Murray at Harvard University’s Kennedy School of Government found that around two-thirds of scholarship recipients have household incomes below $75,000, showing that the program benefits students from both low- and middle-income families.76

Arizona also implemented the Corporate Income Tax Tuition Credit and the Corporate Income Credit for Disabled/Displaced Students; the programs are similar to the individual credit. Corporations may donate to school tuition organizations and then claim the credit against their state income tax. However, there is a statewide cap on the total amount donated: $20 million for the tuition credit and $5 million for the disabled/displaced credit. Donations are accepted on a first-come first-serve basis. The total cap on corporate contributions has been rising but total donations have remained stable at around $11 million.77 Because all Arizona’s school tuition organizations are 501(c)(3) organizations, donations are also deductible for federal tax purposes.

The tax credit for donations to school tuition organizations reduces state revenues. However, local governments save money when students switch from public to private schools. The Goldwater Institute notes that it is possible for the program to be revenue neutral if money saved by transferring students offsets the forgone revenues.78 In any case, it is important to look at both the saving and cost side of the equation. States facing an influx of students to the public school system and the rising costs that accompany them could institute a similar tax credit to control costs. New Jersey, for example, faces an influx of former private school students due to parochial school closings and declining parochial enrollment.79

Eleven states have implemented tax credit programs, but 10 of them either limit scholarships to low income students, do not award a 100 percent credit or cap total donations.80  None of these programs allow individuals to take the credit for tuition paid for their own children or any other specific student. A total of 13 states and the District of Columbia, or parts thereof, have some form of voucher program. [See Figure IV.]  This includes six states that also have tax credit programs. An additional seven states have only tax credit programs.

Benefits of Reimbursing Private School Tuition for Texas Students (K-12)

When schools compete, performance improves. The primary goal of reimbursing parents for tuition at private and parochial schools is to improve education outcomes for all students, public and private. By increasing the number and variety of schools competing for students and teachers, public schools would have incentives to improve, students would be matched with the schools, teachers and curricula that best meet their needs, and both public and private schools would have incentives to become more efficient.

Properly structured, a voucher program could also increase the funding per student available to local public schools and/or plug the state’s budget deficit. For example, calculations made for the Texas Taxpayer Savings Grants program show that if the projected number of students switch from public to private schools using a voucher equal to 60 percent of the state’s average spending on management and operations, the funds available to the state or local public schools would increase by approximately $473 per student, annually.81

Benefits to Public School Students. A voucher program would benefit public school students through improved school and teacher performance. The present public education system fails to provide teachers with the tools and freedom they need to do their jobs well.82 Indeed, teachers in private schools report having much more authority over how and what they teach, and more support to do their job well.83 Moreover, school choice would allow parents to choose schools that fit their requirements of quality of curriculum, religious values, quality of instruction, moral values, school climate and class size.84

School choice increases competition, which makes schools and students more productive. Greater productivity yields higher achievement, such as more students passing the Texas Assessment of Academic Skills and Texas Assessment of Knowledge and Skills standardized tests, and more students graduating and attending post-secondary education.85

Allowing greater choice in schools will also help ease the pressure for new public school buildings and personnel, therefore allowing students in public schools to benefit by having more resources allocated per student.86  In addition, parents’ freedom to choose among diverse offerings will free schools and teachers to specialize in what they do best.87

Benefits to Public Schools. Not only will public school students benefit from tuition vouchers, the schools themselves will prosper as well. When a student chooses to attend a private school, the expense to taxpayers of educating them will also drop, causing the funds per-pupil for public education to rise. Schools in a competitive environment cannot afford to waste money on bureaucracy and other elements that do not manifest in the classroom. Administrators will have a strong incentive to cut spending on bureaucracy and consultants in order to compete for students and the best teachers. According to education analyst Andrew Coulson, “Arizona public schools would have to hire roughly 25,000 more teachers and dismiss 21,210 non-teaching employees” to rival the private sector.88  Assuming that any savings (net of the cost of vouchers for private school students) are allocated to the local public schools the former students would otherwise attend, local school districts will benefit.89

Moreover, specialization by school, rather than costly specialization within large schools, will make schools much more manageable, which can help reduce overall costs. Specialization can also save money by eliminating duplication of services.90

Benefits to Public School Teachers. Public school teachers will benefit by having more manageable classrooms and increased pay. Increased demand for teachers would raise public school teachers’ pay by an average of $2,173 to $2,843, according to calculations based on the Texas Taxpayer Savings Grant program. In highly competitive areas, such as Houston, teacher pay could increase by as much as $12,000 annually.91 Since the resulting competition would yield higher incomes for master teachers, rivalry for successful and bright teachers would also cause teaching to become a more desirable profession.92

Classroom achievements that please parents would increase enrollments and budgets, thereby raising teacher market value. Evidence that competition and choice improve working conditions for teachers comes from the experience of teachers in private schools.93 With broad-based school choice expansion, more teachers would apply directly to the campuses where they want to work, thereby increasing teacher mobility and location choice and reducing teacher vulnerability to arbitrary or personal administrative decisions. By enabling teachers to find the students and parents who share their educational philosophy and need their special skills, school choice could make teaching a pleasure instead of a chore for many teachers.94

Benefits to Taxpayers. Net savings to the state from public school student switching could be approximately $2 billion in the first two years of the program.95 In fact, a Johns Hopkins University study found that seven of the 11 most prominent choice programs in existence between 1990 and 2004 helped save their states at least $1 million. Those that did not save money — Utah’s Carson Smith voucher program and the two-century-old “town tuitioning” programs in Maine and Vermont — were neutral in their financial impacts. The study also found that these same voucher programs helped save state governments $22 million and local school districts $422 million since their enactment.96

Indeed, there is no evidence that any of the various voucher and tax credit programs throughout the United States have caused additional costs to state and local governments. States and public school districts could in fact save money every time a public school student transfers to a private school. In Texas, for example:

Texas spent an average of $8,714 per public school student during the 2010-2011 school year.97

Reimbursing parents 60 percent of the public school expense for educating that child would leave 40 percent of the amount available to the state.

Benefits to Cities and Counties. School choice would lead to increased private economic development. For example, the Edgewood voucher program in San Antonio increased the desirability of living and investing in the area. An evaluation of the program’s economic impact found it attracted significant migration into the district and additional business development; so much, in fact, that in several years of rapid growth in voucher use, public school district enrollment grew as well.98  During the 10 years the Edgewood voucher program was operational, San Antonio saw a sharp rise in economic activity, with a boom in commercial real estate and a significant increase in commercial and industrial property values.99

Empowering parents to choose a schooling provider through increased choice will allow more efficient and effective producers to gain market share.100 Since choice schools will also pay for the expense of building new schools that will house their students, local school districts will benefit from not having to necessarily pay for all of the new construction costs.

Parents’ ability to supplement the voucher funding will further reduce overall costs for state and local governments, as the revenue gained by school entrepreneurs will help fund their expansion, and will enable them to be less dependent on voucher funds.101

Benefit to Homeowners. Higher property values would result from school choice. Better performing schools raise the value of residential property relative to other parts of the city. Consider that although most homes in the exclusive Dallas enclave of Highland Park are inside the Highland Park Independent School District, part of Highland Park is in the Dallas Independent School District — a large, inner-urban school system. An informal study by Dallas attorney Martin Gibson compared Highland Park home prices in the Highland Park Independent School District to Highland Park home prices in the Dallas Independent School District and found that, all else equal, homes on the Highland Park Independent School District side of the street sold for 24 percent more than those on the Dallas Independent School District side. This implies that many Highland Park homeowners paid about $72,000 just for the right to send their children to Highland Park schools.102  The price of a single-family home in the Edgewood ISD increased $6,500, on average, and the school district netted an additional $15 million in property taxes and per-pupil payments from the state during the 10 years of the voucher program.103 

Benefits to the Community. Genuine opportunity for parental choice from a diverse menu of schooling options will create some rivalry, and perhaps, eventually, even the full-blown competition that is a proven agent of efficiency and relentless improvement. If public schools must vie for a share of the education market, each school has to attain a choice worthiness level, probably by specializing in something that exploits its strengths, while also addressing the most critical schooling needs of their surrounding communities.104

Benefits to Private School Students, Parents and Schools. Smaller, more specialized schools will enhance the community feel of schools by enabling teachers, school administrators and parents to play a greater, more personal role in the education of students.105 Specialization and school choice can also enhance educationally beneficial, and legally mandated, ethnic and racial diversity.106 In addition, parents will benefit from lower educational costs.

Transferring students will also increase the enrollment in private schools and generate more money for those schools.

Conclusion

Over the years, providing families with a diverse menu of public and private school options will significantly reduce system-wide problems such as falling productivity, discipline issues and high drop-out rates. A broad school choice program in Texas will provide families with greater opportunities and better alternatives. An education voucher program for all Texas K-12 students will not reduce current funding per public school student and there will be no added net cost to taxpayers. The NCPA study projects that a voucher worth $6,667 would initiate a 450,000 public school student shift to private schools, creating over $1.87 billion in savings over two years. A 60 percent uptake by private school students would yield approximately $580 million in savings in two years. Some of the benefits from the implementation of the program include increased teacher pay, higher public school performance and standards, more savings for schools and taxpayers, greater school choice for families and increased competition will give public schools an incentive to improve. A properly implemented school voucher program gives families more control over their educational spending, and enables them to spend that money on the tuition of a school that is the best for their children.

Endnotes

1. The authors wish to acknowledge and express their thanks to NCPA research associates who assisted with the preparation of this report:  Farhaud Mirzadeh, Wasif Huda, Robert Wieland, Kyle Buckley and Senior Fellow Pamela Villarreal.

2. Carolyn M. Hoxby, “Productivity in Education: The Quintessential Upstream Industry,” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 7, No. 2, 2004, pages 209-231.

3. Larry Cuban et al., Against the Odds (Fitchburg, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2010).

4. Texas Education Agency, “2010-2011 Actual Financial data, Totals for State Total (All Districts).”

5. National Education Association, “Rankings & Estimates: Rankings of the States 2011 and Estimates of School Statistics 2012,” NEA Research, page 95, December 2011. Available at http://www.nea.org/assets/docs/NEA_Rankings_And_Estimates_FINAL_20120209.pdf.

6. Texas Education Agency, “Snapshot 2011,” 2012. Available at http://ritter.tea.state.tx.us/perfreport/snapshot/2011/state.html. Access verified November 6, 2012.

7. Texas Education Agency, “Secondary School Completion and Dropouts in Texas Public Schools 2006-07,” Division of Accountability, Research Department of Assessment, Accountability, and Data Quality, August 2008. Available at http://www.tea.state.tx.us/acctres/dropcomp_index.html. Texas Education Agency, “Secondary School Completion and Dropouts in Texas Public Schools 2006-07,” Division of Accountability, Research Department of Assessment, Accountability, and Data Quality, August 2008. Available at http://www.tea.state.tx.us/acctres/dropcomp_index.html.

8. Texas Education Agency, “2010-11 State Performance Report.”

9. Institute of Education Sciences, “NAEP Overview,” 2012. Available at http://nces.ed.gov/nationsreportcard/about/.

10. The NAEP is the nation’s largest continuing, uniform test of academic performance. Institute of Education Sciences, “State Profiles: Texas.”

11. Institute of Education Sciences, “State Profiles,” 2012. Available at http://nces.ed.gov/nationsreportcard/states/. Access verified November 5, 2012.

12. Fred M. Newman, Student Engagement and Achievement in American Secondary Schools (New York: Teachers College Press, 1992), pages 2-3.

13. Committee on Increasing High School Students’ Engagement and Motivation to Learn, Engaging Schools: Fostering High School Students Motivation to Learn (Washington, D.C.: National Academics Press, 2004).

14. Jeremy D. Finn and Donald A. Rock, “Academic Success among Students At-Risk,” Journal of Applied Psychology, Vol. 82, 1997, pages 221-234; Elizabeth A. Linnenbrink and Paul R. Pintrich, “Motivation as an Enabler for Academic Success,” School Psychology Review, Vol. 31, No. 3, 2002, page 313; Earnest W. Brewer and David N. Burgess, “Professor’s Role in Motivating Students to Attend Class,” Journal of Industrial Teacher Education, Vol. 42, No. 3, 2005, page 24; and Herbert J. Walberg, Advancing Student Achievement (Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Institution Press, 2010).

15. Poonam C. Dev, “Intrinsic Motivation and Academic Achievement: What Does their Relationship Imply for the Classroom Teacher?”  Remedial and Special Education, Vol. 18, No. 1, 1997, pages 12-19. W.E. Blank, “Authentic Instruction,” in W.E. Blank & Sandra Harwell, eds., Promising Practices for Connecting High School to the Real World (Tampa, Fla.: University of South Florida, 1997), pages 15-21. Carole Ames, “Classrooms: Goals, Structures, and Student Motivation,” Journal of Educational Psychology, Vol. 84, No. 3, 1992, pages 261-271. Jeremy D. Finn, “Withdrawing from School,” Review of Educational Research, Vol. 59, 1989, pages 117-142; and Richard R. Hake, “Interactive-Engagement versus Traditional Methods: A Six-Thousand-Student Survey of Mechanics Test Data for Introductory Physics Courses,” American Journal of Physics, Vol. 66, No. 1, 1998, pages 64-74.

16. Robert Blum, School Connectedness: Improving the Lives of Students (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Bloomberg School of Public Health, 2005), page 4.

17. Mary Ainley, “Interest in Learning in the Disposition of Curiosity in Secondary Students:  Investigating Process and Context,” in Hoffman, Lore, et al., eds., Interest and Learning:  Proceedings of the Seeon Conference on Interests and Gender (Kiel, Germany: IPN, 1998), pages 257-266; Ann Renninger, “Individual Interest and Its Implications for Understanding Intrinsic Motivation,” in Carol Sansone and Judith M. Harackiewicz, eds., Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation: The Search for Optimum Motivation and Performance (New York: Academic Press, 2000), pages 373-404; and Ulrich Schiefele, “Topic Interest, Text Representation, and Quality of Experience,” Contemporary Educational Psychology, Vol. 21, 1996, pages 3-18.

18. Rita S. Dunn, Kenneth J. Dunn, & Gary E. Price, Learning Style Inventory (Lawrence, Kansas: Price Systems, 1975, 1979, 1981, 1985, 1989).

19. Arthur G. Powell, Eleanor Farrar and David K Cohen, The Shopping Mall High School: Winners and Losers in the Educational Marketplace (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1985).

20. Committee on Increasing High School Students’ Engagement and Motivation to Learn, National Research Council, “Engaging Schools,” 2004, page 19.

21. Byron Brown, “Why Governments Run Schools,” Economics of Education Review, Vol. 11, No. 4, 1992, pages 287-300.

22. Mark Holmes, The Reformation of Canada’s Schools (Montreal: McGill-Queens University Press, 1998).

23. Lydia Segal, Battling Corruption in America’s Public Schools (Boston: Northeastern University Press, 2004).

24. John Merrifield, “The Twelve Policy Approaches to Increased School Choice,” Journal of School Choice, Vol. 2, No. 1, Winter 2008, pages 3-20.

25. Gary Orfield et al., “The Growth of Segregation in American Schools: Changing Patterns of Separation and Poverty since 1968,” National School Boards Association, Washington, D.C., Council of Urban Boards of Education, 1993.

26. Susan Black, “Engaging the Disengaged,” American School Board Journal, Vol. 190, No. 12, December 2003, pages 58-60, 71.

27. Marcia Gentry, Robert K. Gable and Penny Springer, “Gifted and Nongifted Middle School Students: Are Their Attitudes Toward School Different as Measured by the New Affective Instrument, My Class Activities…?” Journal for the Education of the Gifted, Vol. 24, No. 1, 2000, pages 74-96; and Carmel M. Diezmann and James J. Watters, “Bright but Bored: Optimizing the Environment for Gifted Children.” Australian Journal of Early Childhood, Vol. 22, No. 2, 1997, pages 17-21.

28. Susan Black, “Engaging the Disengaged.”

29. American Educational Research Association, American Psychological Association and National Council on Measurement in Education Joint Committee, Standards for Educational and Psychological Testing (Washington, D.C.: American Psychological Association, 1985); Peter W. Airasian, Classroom Assessment: Concepts & Applications, second edition (New York: McGraw-Hill Inc., 1994); and  Richard J. Stiggins, Student-Centered Classroom Assessment, second edition (Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Merrill, an imprint of Prentice Hall, 2009).

30. “The MetLife Survey of the American Teacher: Collaborating for Student Success,” 2009.

31. Laurence Steinberg, Beyond the Classroom:  Why School Reform Has Failed and What Parents Need to Do (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1996).

32. Susan Black, “Engaging the Disengaged.”

33. A. Gary Dworkin, “Coping with Reform: The Intermix of Teacher Morale, Teacher Burnout, and Teacher Accountability,” in Bruce J. Biddle, Thomas L. Good and Ivor F. Goodson, eds., International Handbook of Teachers and Teaching, Volume 1 (Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1997), chapter 13; and Seymour B. Sarason, The Predictable Failure of Educational Reform (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass Publishers, 1990), pages 25-26. Alec M. Gallup, “Gallup Poll of Teachers Attitudes toward the Public Schools,” (Bloomington, Ind.: Phi Delta Kappa, 1985).

34. Paul Peterson, Saving Schools (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2010), page 95.

35. Lisa Delpit, Other People’s Children (New York: The New Press, 1995).

36. Hugh B. Price, “The Preparation Gap,” Education Week, November 28, 2001.

37. Frederick M. Hess, Education Unbound: The Promise and Practice of Greenfield Schooling (Alexandria, Va.: ASCD, 2010); and John Merrifield, The School Choice Wars (Lanhan, Md.: Roman & Littlefield Education, 2001).

38. Eric A. Hanushek, “The Failure of Input-Based Schooling Policies,” Economic Journal, Vol. 113, No. 485, 2003, pages F64-F98.

39. Eric Hirsch, Julia E. Koppich and Micheal S. Knapp, “What States Are Doing to Improve the Quality of Teaching:  A Brief Review of Current Patterns and Trends,” CTP working paper, University of Washington, Center for the Study of Teaching and Policy, 2001.

40. Terry M. Moe, “Teacher Unions and the Public Schools,” in Terry M. Moe, ed., A Premier on America’s Schools (Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Institution Press, 2001), pages 151-183.

41. Drew H. Gitomer, Andrew S. Latham and Robert Ziomek, “The Academic Quality of Prospective Teachers:  The Impact of Admission and Licensure Testing,” Educational Testing Services, 1999.

42. Jean Protsik, “History of Teacher Pay and Incentive Reforms,” Office of Educational Research and Improvement, paper presented at the Conference on Teacher Compensation of the Consortium for Policy Research in Education, Washington, D.C., November 2-4, 1994.

43. Ibid.

44. Dale Ballou, “Do Public Schools Hire the Best Applicants?”  Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 111, 1996, pages 97-134; David Grissmer and Sheila N. Kirby, Patterns of Attrition among Indiana Teachers 1965-1987 (Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation, 1992). Iris Weiss and S.E. Boyd, Where Are They Now? A Follow-Up Study of the 1985-86 Science and Mathematics Teaching Force (Chapel Hill, N.C.: Horizon Research, 1990); Edward Liu et al., “When Districts Encounter Teacher Shortages? The Challenges of Recruiting and Retaining Math Teachers in Urban Districts,” Leadership and Policy in Schools, Vol. 7, No. 3, 2008, pages 296-323; and National Commission on Mathematics and Science Teaching for the 21st Century (the Glenn Commission), Before It’s Too Late (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 2000).

45. Rolf Blank, Doreen Langesen and Adam Petermann, “State Indicators of Science and Mathematics Education 2007,” Council of Chief State School Officers, 2007.

46. Richard M. Ingersoll, “The Problem of Under-Qualified Teachers in American Secondary Schools,” Educational Researcher, Vol. 28, No. 2, March 1999, pages 26-37.

47. Linda Darling-Hammond, “Teachers and Teaching:  Testing Policy Hypotheses from a National Commission report,” Educational Researcher, Vol. 27, No. 1, 1998, pages 5-15.

48. John Pisciotta, “School Accountability: Top-Down or Bottom-Up?” Texas Public Policy Foundation, October 2001.

49. Committee on Increasing High School Students’ Engagement and Motivation to Learn, National Research Council, “Engaging Schools,” 2004, page 19.

50. John Pisciotta, “School Accountability,” 2001.

51. Ibid.

52. Christopher Mazzeo and Ilene Berman, “Reaching New Heights: Turning Around Low-Performing Schools,” National Governors Center for Best Practices, August 2003.

53. Eva L. Baker, “Can We Fairly Measure the Quality of Education?” CSE Tech. Rep. No. 290, University of California, Center for Research on Evaluation, Standards, and Student Testing, 1989. Joan L. Herman and Shari Golan, “Priorities of Educational Testing and Evaluation: The Testimony of the CRESST National Faculty,” CSE Tech. Rep. No. 304, University of California, Center for the Study of Evaluation, 1989. Lorrie A. Shepard, “Inflated Test Score Gains: Is It Old Norms or Teaching the Test?”  Educational Measurement: Issues and Practices, Vol. 9, No. 3, 1990, pages 15-22. Jennifer McMurrer, “Choices, Changes, and Challenges: Curriculum and Instruction in the NCLB Era,” Center on Education Policy, 2007.

54. Diane Ravitch, The Death and Life of the Great American School System (New York: Basic Books, 2010).

55. John Merrifield and Jesse A. Ortiz, “Reinventing the Kansas K-12 School System to Engage More Children in Productive Learning,” Kansas Policy Institute, October 2011. Available at http://www.kansaspolicy.org/researchcenters/education/studies/79705.aspx.

56. Matt Moore, “NCPA’s Value-Added Report Card on Texas Schools: A Model for Meaningful Assessments,” National Center for Policy Analysis, Brief Analysis No. 446, July 9, 2003. Available at http://www.ncpathinktank.org/pub/ba446.

57. John Merrifield and Joseph L. Bast, “Budget Impact of the Texas Taxpayers’ Saving Grant Program,” Heartland Institute, Policy Brief, April 2011. Available at http://heartland.org/policy-documents/budget-impact-texas-taxpayers%e2%80%99-savings-grant-program.

58. John Merrifield, “The School Choice Evidence and Its Significance,” Journal of School Choice, Vol. 2, No. 3.

59. National Center for Education Statistics, “Table 67. Private elementary and secondary schools, enrollment, teachers, and high school graduates, by state: Selected years, 1999 through 2009.”

60. John Merrifield and Joseph L. Bast, “Budget Impact of the Texas Taxpayers’ Savings Grant Program,” Heartland Institute, April 2011.

61. Lance T. Izumi, Vicki E. Murray and Rachel S. Chaney, Not as Good as you Think: Why the Middle Class Needs School Choice (San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute, 2007), page 180.

62. “As New School Year Approaches Catholic Donors Continue to See Empty Seats, Rising Costs and Charters Taking A Toll On Parochial Schools,” Foundations and Donors Interested in Catholic Activities, July 23, 2010. Available at http://www.fadica.org/main/News/tabid/123/ctl/ArticleView/mid/454/articleId/4/As-New-School-Year-Approaches-Catholic-Donors-Continue-to-See-Empty-Seats-Rising-Costs-and-Charters-Taking-A-Toll-On-Parochial-Schools.aspx.

63. Adam B. Schaeffer, “School Tax Credit Can Help Kids and the State,” Newark Star-Ledger, December 15, 2008. Available at http://www.cato.org/publications/commentary/school-tax-credit-can-help-kids-state.

64. John Merrifield and Joseph L. Bast, “Budget Impact of the Texas Taxpayers’ Savings Grant Program.”

65. Ed Sterling, “Comptroller Lays Out Options for Texas Budget Writing Panel,” Hays Free Press, March 9, 2011. Available at http://haysfreepress.com/archives/16927.

66. Joseph L. Bast, “Corrections to Fiscal Note for Taxpayers’ Savings Grants Program,” Heartland Institute, June 8, 2011. Available at http://heartland.org/policy-documents/corrections-fiscal-note-taxpayers-savings-grants-program.

67. Barry R. Chiswick and Stella Koutroumanes, “An Econometric Analysis of the Demand for Private Schooling,” Research in Labor Economics, Vol. 15, 1996, pages 209-237.

68. John Merrifield and Joseph L. Bast, “Budget Impact of the Texas Taxpayers’ Saving Grant Program,” Heartland Institute, Policy Brief, April 2011.

69. Since the program modeled allows current private school students to receive the voucher, the methodology is slightly different from that used to model the Texas Taxpayer Savings Grants Program. It is not assumed that some students will shift from private to public schools in order to qualify for the voucher.

70. Barry R. Chiswick and Stella Koutroumanes, “An Econometric Analysis of the Demand for Private Schooling.”

71. Because the C&K coefficient applies to the entire school-age population, both public and private school students must be included in the calculation.

72. John Merrifield and Joseph L. Bast, “Budget Impact of the Texas Taxpayers’ Saving Grant Program,” Heartland Institute, Policy Brief, April 2011.

73. Parochial schools alone save taxpayers $0.7 billion per year, based on the estimated number of private school students in Texas and average spending per public school student.

74. Texas Education Agency, “School Finance 101: Funding of Texas Public Schools,” Fall 2012. Available at http://www.tea.state.tx.us/index4.aspx?id=7022.

75. Allan E. Parker, “Texas Taxpayers Savings Grants, Courts and the Constitution,” Justice Foundation, San Antonio, Texas, undated.

76. Vicki E. Murray, “An Analysis of Arizona Individual Income Tax-credit Scholarship Recipients’ Family,” Harvard University Program on Education and Governance, 2010. Available at http://www.hks.harvard.edu/pepg/PDF/Papers/PEPG10-18_Murray.pdf.

77. State of Arizona Department of Revenue, “Private School Tuition Organization Income Tax Credits in Arizona: A Summary of Activity FY 2011.” Available at http://www.azdor.gov/Portals/0/Reports/2011-Private-School-Tuition-Organization-Individual-and-Corporate-Income-Tax-Credit-Report.pdf.

78. Carrie Lips Lukas, “The Arizona Scholarship Tax Credit: Providing Choice for Arizona Taxpayers and Students,” Goldwater Institute, Policy Report No. 186, December 11, 2003.

79. Adam B. Schaeffer, “School Tax Credit Can Help Kids and the State.”

80. National Conference of State Legislatures, “Tuition Tax Credits.” Available at http://www.ncsl.org/issues-research/educ/school-choice-scholarship-tax-credits.aspx.

81. Marc Oestreich and Joseph L. Bast, “Texas Taxpayers’ Savings Grants: Q&A No. 4 – Taking the Best Kids,” Heartland Institute, August 24, 2012. Available at http://heartland.org/policy-documents/texas-taxpayers-savings-grants-qa-no-4-taking-best-kids.

82. Joseph L. Bast, Herbert J. Walberg and Bruno Behrend, “How Teachers in Texas Would Benefit from Expanding School Choice,” Heartland Institute, April 2011.

83. Ibid.

84. Patras Bukhari and Vance Randall, “Exit and Entry: Why Parents in Utah Left Public Schools and Chose Private Schools,” Journal of School Choice, Vol. 3, Issue 3, October 2009.

85. John W. Diamond, “Should Texas Adopt a School Choice Program?” Texas Public Policy Foundation, March 2007.

86. John Merrifield and Jesse A. Ortiz. Jr., “Reinventing the Kansas K-12 School System to Engage More Children in Productive Learning,” E.G. West Institute for Effective Schooling, July 2010.

87. Patras Bukhari and Vance Randall, “Exit and Entry: Why Parents in Utah Left Public Schools and Chose Private Schools.”

88. Andrew Coulson, “Arizona Public and Private Schools: A Statistical Analysis,” Goldwater Institute of Policy Report #213, October 17, 2006.

89. John Merrifield and Jesse A. Ortiz. Jr., “Reinventing the Kansas K-12 School System to Engage More Children in Productive Learning.”

90. Ibid.

91. Joseph L. Bast, Herbert J. Walberg and Bruno Behrend, “How Teachers in Texas Would Benefit from Expanding School Choice,” Heartland Institute, April 2011.

92. John Merrifield and Jesse A. Ortiz. Jr., “Reinventing the Kansas K-12 School System.”

93. Joseph L. Bast, Herbert J. Walberg, Ph.D. and Bruno Behrend, “How Teachers in Texas Would Benefit from Expanding School Choice.”

94. Richard K. Vedder, “Can Teachers Own Their Own Schools?” Independence Institute Policy Report, 2000.

95. John Merrifield and Joseph L. Bast, “Budget Impact of the Texas Taxpayers’ Savings Grant Program.”

96. John Merrifield and Jesse A. Ortiz. Jr., “Reinventing the Kansas K-12 School System.”

97. Texas Education Agency, “2010-2011 Actual Financial data, Totals for State Total (All Districts).”

98. John Merrifield and Jesse A. Ortiz. Jr., “Reinventing the Kansas K-12 School System.”

99. John Merrifield and Nathan Gray, “San Antonio’s Edgewood Voucher Program Shows Benefits of Choice,” Heartland Institute, February 28, 2011.

100. John Merrifield and Jesse A. Ortiz. Jr., “Reinventing the Kansas K-12 School System.”

101. Ibid.

102. John C. Goodman and Matt Moore, “School Choice vs. School Choice,” National Center for Policy Analysis, Policy Backgrounder No. 155, April 2001. Available at http://www.ncpathinktank.org/pub/bg155.

103. John Merrifield and Nathan Gray, “San Antonio’s Edgewood Voucher Program Shows Benefits of Choice,” Heartland Institute, February 28, 2011.

104. John Merrifield and Jesse A. Ortiz. Jr., “Reinventing the Kansas K-12 School System.”

105. Ibid.

106. Ibid.